Skip to main content

A new analytical approach for identifying market contagion

Abstract

This study proposed a new analytical approach to identify the excessive comovement of two markets as contagion. This goal is achieved by linking latent-factor and single-equation error correction models and evaluating the breaks in the short- and long-term relationships and correlatedness in the linked model. The results demonstrated that a short-term relationship representing the market speed ratio between two markets plays a key role in contagion dynamics. When a long-term relationship or correlatedness is broken (comovement change) due to a break in the short-term relationship (market speed ratio), contagion is highly likely and should be formally declared. Bayesian posterior probabilities were calculated to determine the cause. Furthermore, this study applied this analytical Bayesian approach to empirically test the contagion effects of the U.S. stock market during the global financial crisis between 2007 and 2009 using 22 developed equity markets.

Introduction

Over the past 40 years, financial markets have become increasingly integrated. Market integration began with open markets, in which asset prices were determined globally. The relevant literature emerged in the 1970s, with early theoretical developments in international asset-pricing models. Since then, a growing body of evidence supporting the argument that risk premia are determined globally has accumulated. These days, market integration is often tested using “equality” in risk pricing based on an asset-pricing benchmark or “the law of one price” to avoid arbitrage between variables, such as prices or interest rates. These definitions of financial market integration suggest that integration leads to the conversion of market-specific risk into common risk (Lehkonen 2015). It is strongly argued that an integrated market leads to enhanced economic growth and stability through direct financial channels, such as lower capital costs and increased investment opportunities (Carrieri et al. 2007). Global financial integration has some detractors. One major criticism is that it significantly raises global market volatility during a crisis and causes financial markets to be more vulnerable to global shocks. Since the onset of the global financial crisis (GFC) between 2007 and 2009, periodic local financial crises have occurred worldwide, and market contagion has become one of the most researched topics in the study of financial markets. Gagnon and Karolyi (2006) surveyed the history of financial market contagion and identified volatility spillover as the major driving force behind crisis contagion.

Extant literature has clearly demonstrated that disentangling contagion from market interdependence is crucial for singling out contagion in the event of a financial crisis. Market contagion is measured by a significant increase in the correlation between two markets. One major pitfall in correctly identifying contagion is that it is not simply shown by an increased correlation of performance indicators during a crisis period. The increasing correlation coefficient is somewhat flawed due to the interference of rising volatility, which is commonly associated with periods of financial stress (Forbes and Rigobon 2002). To overcome this, most contagion tests define contagion as “a correlation in excess of that expected via fundamentals” (Bekaert et al. 2005, p.40). However, Bekaert et al. (2005) acknowledged the difficulty in “identifying both the relevant fundamentals and how they are linked to correlation” (p.40).

Thus, contagion tests have been redefined continuously over the years, as the sources of correlation biases or correlation increases due to relevant fundamentals are identified by removing confounding effects.Footnote 1 This process started with Forbes and Rigobon (2002), who noted that cross-market correlation increases during crisis periods due to “common as well as market-specific factors” (p.2225). As the volatility of the target market may change due to common and market-specific factors, many studies use factor decomposition models to identify contagion (Bekaert et al. 2005; Corsetti et al. 2001, 2005; Dungey et al. 2005a, b; Dungey and Martin 2001; Forbes and Rigobon 2002).Footnote 2 Bekeart et al. (2014) defined contagion as “the comovement in excess of that implied by the factor model” (p.2598), which is an improvement on the old definition (Bekaert et al. 2005), as it is not limited to correlation increase as a contagion measurement.

To investigate the comovement defined by Bekeart et al. (2014) more precisely, this study linked the latent factor model (LFM) and the single equation error correction model (SEECM). The LFM assumes market-specific and common systematic volatilities to describe market returns under market integration. The SEECM describes the dynamic process of market returns to equilibrium from a state of disequilibrium due to a shock, assuming that two market return time series exhibit a linear equilibrium relationship that determines short- and long-term behavior (Banerjee et al. 1990, 1993; Davidson et al. 1978). By linking the two models via first-order autoregressive (AR[1]) errors, this study described stressful market situations more precisely. The major strength of linking the two models is the ability to establish the null market integration hypothesis (MIH) for tranquil periods and analyze the contagion structurally via a causal relation between two markets for crisis periods. This reveals that the short-term relationship, that is, the common-factor loading, is the main backbone of the linked model and is entirely embedded in the long-term relationship and correlatedness between two markets. These findings allow for an accurate and concise definition of contagion: contagion is defined as an occurrence of breaks in the long-term relationship or correlatedness between two markets mainly caused by breaks in the short-term relationship. This definition is reasonable, as contagion would be in effect when the short-term effect of a shock is not properly controlled at the beginning of the crisis period and continues to cause breaks in the long-term relationship or correlatedness between two markets. From the market behavior perspective, long-term relationships or correlatedness may be considered comovements, while short-term effects may be considered the market speed ratio (MSR) of two market movements under integration, which depends on liquidity and possibility of downside risk (Eq. 7).

This approach leads to the consideration of various situations as potential alternatives when a shock hits a source market (Table 1). The originality of this approach is the application of the Bayesian method to those situations in order to identify contagion. This study used the Bayesian method to analytically detect comovement in excess of that expected from fundamentals, identifying it as contagion. When comovement (long-term relationship or correlatedness) between the target and source markets is broken, the cause is determined by calculating posterior probabilities. If the cause is a short-term (MSR) break, the contagion is formally addressed.

Identifying contagion based on comovement involves two critical issues (Dungey and Renault 2018): (1) how correlation is related to common and market-specific factors during tranquil and crisis periods (Bekaert et al. 2005; Corsetti et al. 2005; Dungey and Martin 2007; Dungey et al. 2010, 2011; Forbes and Rigobon 2002) and (2) how all time-varying components of return volatilities are related to structural breaks during crisis times (Aït-Sahalia et al. 2015; Bae et al. 2003; Baur and Schulze 2005; Boyson et al. 2010; Bussetti and Harvey 2011; Favero and Giavazzi 2002; Rodriguez 2007). The present approach completely resolves these two critical issues, as demonstrated below.

The empirical part of this study involves applying the Bayesian approach to address the financial market contagion between the U.S. and other countries under market integration during the GFC between 2007 and 2009. This study evaluated the contagion effects of the U.S. stock market during the GFC using 22 developed equity markets. The results revealed that some countries suffered from financial contagion from the U.S. market crash, while others managed to escape contagion. Some key contagion parameters, such as short- and long-term effects, correlatedness between source and target markets, and contagion odds, must be monitored during a financial stress. An increase in short- and long-term effects or correlatedness suggests potential contagion. These contagion parameters could help policymakers and investors develop alternative and practical guidelines against contagion.

Identifying contagion is vital not only in financial markets but also in macroeconomic dynamics. Kalemli-Ozcan et al. (2013) and Beck (2021) demonstrated the necessity of identifying contagion to establish the link between financial integration and business cycle synchronization in European Union countries. The present approach to identify contagion is promising in its application to analyzing contagion phenomena in various macroeconomic and financial market variables across international markets.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. First, the market model and market integration hypothesis are discussed. Next, contagion dynamics and the Bayesian testing procedure are described. Following this, the major findings for the 2008 US market crisis are presented. Finally, concluding remarks are provided.

Methods

Market modeling under integration

Linking the latent factor and single equation error correction models

The latent factor model Eq. 10 (LFM, Appendix 1) was linked to the single equation error correction model Eq. 11 (SEECM, Appendix 2) to model the market dynamics between two markets under integration. This linking process yields a proper model for identifying contagion using a Bayesian approach. To link the two models, we introduced AR(1) errors \(u_{x,t}\) and \(u_{y,t}\) for the LFM, as in Eq. 1. AR(1) errors are useful for describing market behavior during periods of financial stress via the parameter \({\upeta }\). For instance, providing more (or less) information to the market can make \({\upeta }\) close to zero (or close to 1), which indicates iid \(u\). Phillips et al. (2011) investigated the near-explosive process with the AR(1) parameter \({\upeta }\) close to 1 during a crisis period.

Proposition 1

Suppose that we employ an AR(1) model for the idiosyncratic factors \(u_{x,t}\) and \(u_{y,t}\) in Eq.  10 :

$$u_{x,t} = \eta_{x} u_{x,t - 1} + a_{u,t} \quad u_{y,t} = \eta_{y} u_{y,t - 1} + b_{u,t}$$
(1)

where \(E\left( {a_{u,t} W_{t} } \right) = 0, E\left( {a_{u,t} u_{x,t - 1} } \right) = 0, E\left( {b_{u,t} W_{t} } \right) = 0, E\left( {b_{u,t} u_{y,t - 1} } \right) = 0\), \(E\left( {a_{u,t} b_{u,t} } \right) = 0\), \(a_{u,t} \sim iid \left( {0,1} \right), and b_{u,t} \sim iid \left( {0,1} \right).\) This links the LFM to the SEECM as follows:

$$\Delta Y_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt}$$
(2)

where \(\varepsilon_{Lt} = \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t} + (\eta_{x } - \eta_{y } )\theta_{y} W_{t - 1}\) with iid over t, \(0 < \eta_{y} < 1\), and \(Var(\varepsilon_{Lt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2} .\)

Proof of Proposition 1 is provided in Appendix 3.

Remark 1

Composition of the linked model. Using Proposition 1, we obtain the following:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt} \\ & = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma_{L} X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{1t} = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{L2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{Lt} . \\ \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), \(\gamma_{L} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\), and \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) correspond to the short-term effect, long-term effect, and correlatedness of the linked model, respectively.Footnote 3 Thus, the factors that might cause the time-varying comovement (or long-term effect and correlatedness of Eq. 3) during a crisis include the common factors \(W_{t}\) via \(\theta_{x}\) and \(\theta_{y}\) and market-specific factors \(u_{x,t}\) and \(u_{y,t}\) via \(\eta_{x}\) and \(\eta_{y}\). \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) is entirely embedded in \(\gamma_{L}\), \(\beta_{L2}\) and \(\varepsilon_{Lt}\) in Eq. 2. This feature not only plays a key role in formally defining contagion but also resolves various critical issues in identifying contagion, as described below.

Remark 2

Risk parameters. The variances of the idiosyncratic factors of X and Y are \({\text{Var}}\left( {\delta_{x} u_{x,t} } \right) = {\updelta }_{{\text{x}}}^{2} { }/\left( {1 - \eta_{x}^{2} } \right)\) and \({\text{ Var}}\left( {\delta_{y} u_{y,t} } \right) = {\updelta }_{{\text{y}}}^{2} /\left( {1 - \eta_{y}^{2} } \right)\) using Eq. 1, respectively. Thus, market-specific volatility becomes high as \(\eta_{x}\) and \(\eta_{y}\) are close to 1 or \(|{\updelta }_{{\text{x}}} |\) and \(\left| {{\updelta }_{{\text{y}}} } \right|\) are large. According to Proposition 1

\(Var(\varepsilon_{Lt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2}\);

therefore, volatility of \(\Delta Y_{t}\) of the target marketFootnote 4 depends on common and market-specific factors based on their parameters. Volatility increases not only when \({\updelta }_{{\text{y}}}\) becomes large but also when \(\theta_{y}\),\(\updelta _{{\text{x}}}\), and \(\left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2}\) are large. Target market volatility may be decreased by reducing \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2}\) during the financial stress period.

Remark 3

Causality issue. During periods of financial stress with an increased possibility of downside risk, investors tend to exhibit more risk-adverse behavior due to imperfect information. Historically, fears have prompted investors to display herding behavior in the market, which increases the AR(1) parameters \(\eta_{x} \; and\; \eta_{y}\) to close to 1, making them different (Phillips et al. 2011). Different AR(1) parameters (\(\eta_{x} \ne \eta_{y}\)) make \(\varepsilon_{Lt}\) of Eq. 2 depend on \({\text{W}}_{{{\text{t}} - 1}}\), suggesting endogeneity, which usually leads to causality in both directions (from X to Y and from Y to X; Dungey et al. 2005b). This could explain the various breakages in parameters during a crisis.

The market integration hypothesis

The market integration hypothesis (MIH) refers to a tranquil period situation in which market returns X and Y share a common factor with the respective level of risk, and hence, their normal comovement is expected. As Proposition 1 describes the general market dynamics between X and Y, the tranquil period may be based as a null hypothesis against the crisis period.

Proposition 2

Assume the following null MIH:

$$MIH{:}\; \eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0} \;for\;some\;0 < \eta_{0} < 1,\;\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }} \ne 1,\;and\; \theta_{x} \theta_{y} \ne 0$$
(4)

Then, under the null MIH , Eq.  2 can be rewritten as follows:

$$\Delta Y_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Mt}$$
(5)

where \(\varepsilon_{Mt} = \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t}\) is an iid error with \(E\left( {\varepsilon_{Mt} } \right) = 0\) and finite variance of \(Var(\varepsilon_{Mt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2}\) .

Proof of Proposition 2, Eq. 5 easily follows by applying Eq. 4 to Eq. 2.

Remark 4

Basic linear relationship under MIH. Using Proposition 2, we obtain the following:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Mt} \\ & = \beta_{M0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{M1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma_{M} X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Mt} = \beta_{M0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{M1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{M2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{Mt} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\beta_{M0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{M}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), and \({\upbeta }_{{{\text{M}}2}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) correspond to the short-term effect, long-term effect, and correlatedness for the MIH, respectively, and \(\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} } \right) = 0\) when X and Y are in equilibrium. Equation 6 subsequently implies a basic linear relationshipFootnote 5\(Y_{t } = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t}\) \(Y_{t } = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t}\) and the corresponding market speed ratio (MSR) between two markets during a tranquil period; that is,

$$\Delta Y_{t} /\Delta X_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}.$$
(7)

In fact, the MSR equals the short-term effect and holds for general market situations (refer to footnote 5).

Remark 5

Practical meaning of MIH. The null MIH above implies a situation in which two markets are midway between the two extremes of perfect integration into one market and two completely independent markets (Appendix 4). This implies that market-specific volatility is the same in markets X and Y (\({\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} = {\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} = {\upeta }_{0} )\), and that they share a common factor \(\left( {{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} {\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \ne 0} \right)\) with different levels of systematic risk \(\left( {\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }} \ne 1} \right)\). This notion is consistent with the financial market theory, which indicates that only global systematic risks are priced in two fully integrated markets and that integration leads to the conversion of a market-specific risk of each market into a common risk. This implies that local market-specific risks are fully diversified for integrated markets (Lehkonen 2015). In this sense, the MIH achieves two fully integrated markets without any endogeneity problem by allowing \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y}\) in Eq. 1. The parametric condition \(0 < \eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0} < 1\) is essential for the convergence to the equilibrium in Eq. 6 (\(- 1 < \beta_{M1} = - \left( {1 - \eta_{0} } \right){ } < 0\)).

Remark 6

Contagion and the MSR. It is reasonable to discuss market contagion by testing the MIH as a proper null hypothesis. Testing MIH against a crisis enables the detection of comovement change and breaks in long-term effect or correlatedness in excess of those implied by the MIH. As the MSR, being equal to the short-term effect, is actually the relative adjustment speed of market movements to new information from the source market, the MSR is a function of liquidity and possibility of downside risk. Therefore, if the MSR fails to decrease or slow down properly during a stress period, an increase in the comovement (long-term effect or correlatedness) would be unavoidable in excess of that implied by the MIH. Thus, the MSR slowdown during crises is a critical issue in market contagion, as discussed below.

Resolving the two critical issues

The present linked model resolved the two critical issues for identifying contagion based on comovements discussed in the Introduction: (1) how correlation is related to common and market-specific factors during tranquil and crisis periods and (2) how all time-varying components of return volatilities are related to structural breaks in crisis times. Regarding the first issue, Eq. 3 illustrates that correlatedness \(\left( {{\upbeta }_{{{\text{L}}2}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)}}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}{ }} \right)\) is related to a common factor via \(\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\) and to the market-specific factor of X through \(\left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)\) under general situations. Under MIH \({ }\left( {{\upeta }_{y} = \eta_{x} = \eta_{0} } \right)\), these factors are reduced to correlatedness \({\upbeta }_{{{\text{M}}2}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{0} } \right)}}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\) in Eq. 6. During a financial crisis period, \({\upeta }_{y} \ne \eta_{x}\) brings about endogeneity and changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\uptheta _{{\text{y}}} }}{{\uptheta _{{\text{x}}} }},\upeta _{{\text{x}}} ,\upeta _{{\text{y}}} } \right)\), which, in turn, results in increases in correlatedness and long-term effects.

Regarding the second issue, the present linked model defines volatility spillover clearly and simply by considering systematic (common) and market-specific volatility. As \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) is related to systematic volatility and \(\upeta _{{\text{x}}}\) and \(\upeta _{{\text{y}}}\) are related to market-specific volatility, volatility spillover occurs due to changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\uptheta _{{\text{y}}} }}{{\uptheta _{{\text{x}}} }},\upeta _{{\text{x}}} ,\upeta _{{\text{y}}} } \right)\) caused by a shock. These volatility changes cause direct changes in the short-term effect \(\left( {{\upbeta }_{{{\text{L}}0}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }},\;{\text{MSR}}} \right)\), long-term effect \(\left( {{\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)}}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} } \right)}}} \right)\), correlatedness \(\left( {\upbeta _{{{\text{L}}2}} = \frac{{\uptheta _{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 -\upeta _{{\text{x}}} } \right)}}{{\uptheta _{{\text{x}}} }}} \right),\) or convergence speed to equilibrium \((\beta_{L1} = - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\)). When the MIH is rejected or \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{0} , \eta_{0} } \right)\) under the MIH changes to \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }}, \eta_{x}^{{\prime}} , \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)\), the error volatility under the MIH changes from \({\text{Var}}({\upvarepsilon }_{{\text{Mt }}} ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2}\) to:

$${\text{Var}}({\upvarepsilon }_{{\text{Lt }}} ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( { \eta_{x}^{{\prime}} - \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{{\prime} 2} .$$
(8)

Thus, Eq. 8 defines the volatility spillover related to systematic (\(\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }})\) and market-specific element (\(\eta_{x}^{{\prime}}\),\(\eta_{y}^{{\prime}}\)). This explains how all time-varying components of return volatilities are related to structural breaks during crises.

Literature often treats volatility spillover as the tail dependence of market returns. Rodriguez (2007) noted that structural breaks in tail dependence are an actual dimension of contagion effects and tested them using copulas. Bussetti and Harvey (2011) used time-varying copulas to test financial contagion through tail events. Using coexceedance measures or quantiles, a number of studies have detected contagion using the tail (Bae et al. 2003; Baur and Schulze 2005; Boyson et al. 2010). Aït-Sahalia et al. (2015) measured contagion effects via the extreme tail events of mutually exciting jumps. Recently, Dungey and Renault (2018) applied a GARCH (Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity) common feature approach to identify contagion.

A simple illustrative market episode based on this discussion is provided in Appendix 5.

Defining and testing contagion

Defining contagion and testing breaks

A shock that occurs in source market X may cause a break in the established relationship with target market Y during tranquil periods, resulting in contagion. Three types of breaks in market relationships were considered: a break in a short-term relationship, or short-term break (SB), a break in a long-term relationship, or a long-term break (LB), and a break in correlatedness, or a correlatedness break (CRB). Contagion is expected to occur when a shock causes a break in the underlying relationship pertaining to \(\beta_{L0}\) (short-term), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\) (long-term), and \(\beta_{L2}\) (correlatedness) in Eq. 3. As the long-term relationship \(\gamma_{L} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) and correlatedness \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) contain the short-term effect \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\), the short-term effect, which is the MSR, can be used to create the following formal definition of contagion.

Definition

Contagion is declared if a long-term break (a break in \(\gamma_{L} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\)) or a correlatedness break (a break in \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\)) is mainly caused by a short-term break (a break in \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\)).

This definition implies that contagion is declared when the short-term effect (the MSR) of a shock is not properly controlled in a target market at the beginning of the crisis period and continues to cause breaks in the long-term relationship or correlatedness between two markets.Footnote 6

To derive the contagion test, first this study tested whether a shock causes a break in the established linear relationship under the MIH described in Remark 4. Therefore, whether a given period experiences breaks in the relationships pertaining to \(\beta_{M0}\) (short-term effect or MSR), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{M}}}\) (long-term effect), and \(\beta_{M2}\) (correlatedness) in Eq. 6 was tested. To test the null MIH for a given period, the following hypotheses were proposed:

$$H_{0} { }:{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}1}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}1}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} \;\left( {\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\gamma_{L} = \gamma_{{\text{M}}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} ,{\text{ equivalently}}} \right)$$

\(H_{a}\): At least one of the following holds true:

$$\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}1}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}1}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} \ne { }\beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} { }\left( {\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}} ,{ }\gamma_{L} \ne \gamma_{{\text{M}}} ,{ }\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} \ne \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}} ,{\text{ equivalently}}} \right)$$

The null hypothesis \(H_{0}\) illustrates that \(\beta_{M0}\), \(\gamma_{M}\), and \(\beta_{M2}\) are fixed with iid error \({\upvarepsilon }_{{{\text{Mt}}}}\), as noted in Eq. 6. In other words, for a given period, markets X and Y maintain \(\beta_{L0 } = \beta_{{{\text{M}}0}}\), \(\gamma_{L} = \gamma_{{\text{M}}}\), and \(\beta_{L2} = \beta_{{{\text{M}}2}}\) under the MIH. If \(H_{0}\) is rejected, then the MIH fails to hold. In this case, the markets fail to maintain their underlying relationship and experience breaks in the short- or long-term relationship or correlatedness.

We developed a test adopting quantile regression and a Z-test to evaluate such breaks (see Baur 2013 for a more detailed discussion on the advantages of quantile regression). This test is based on the idea that a random fluctuation of the slope estimates around a constant value (with only the intercept parameters systematically increasing as a function of quantile \(\vartheta\)) provides evidence for the iid error of the classical linear regression under the null MIH specified by Eq. 6. If some of the slope coefficients change as a function of quantile \(0 \le \vartheta \le 1,\) it is detected via the Z-test, which is designed to assess the magnitude of the estimated changes in slope for a given quantile. To implement the test, quantile regression parameters were estimated across the entire range of conditional quantiles of \(\Delta Y_{t}\) given \(\Delta X_{t}\). \((\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} ,\gamma_{{\text{L}}} ,\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} )\) was estimated using quantile regression across fixed \(N\) quantiles. Let \(\left( {\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0j}} ,\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}j}} ,\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2j}} } \right)\) be the slope estimates of \(\left( {\beta_{{{\text{L}}0j}} ,\gamma_{{{\text{L}}j}} ,\beta_{{{\text{L}}2j}} } \right)\) from the \(\frac{j}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile regression for \(j = 1, \ldots ,N\). Using the Proposition 3 in the Appendix 6, the Z-test can be derived as follows. Let \(P_{i}\) be \(\left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i1} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{iN} } \right)\), where \(\hat{\upvarphi }_{ij} \left( {i = 1,2,3, j = 1,\ldots,N} \right)\) is the ith slope estimate for one of the three slope estimates (\(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0{\text{j}}}}\), \(\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}j}} , \hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2j}}\)) from the \(\frac{j}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile regression. Let \(P_{ i, - k}\) represent a vector constructed by excluding the kth element from \(P_{i} = \left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i1} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{iN} } \right)\). For instance, \(P_{i, - 1} = \left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i2} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{i,N} } \right)\) and \(P_{i, - N} = \left( {\hat{\varphi }_{i1} , \ldots ,\hat{\varphi }_{i,N - 1} } \right)\). Then,Footnote 7

$${ }Z_{i, k} = \frac{{ \hat{\varphi }_{ik} - m_{k} }}{{s_{k} }}\;{\text{is N}}\left( {0,{1}} \right){\text{ asymptotically}}$$
(9)

with mean \(m_{k}\) and standard deviation \({\text{s}}_{{\text{k}}}\) from \(P_{i, - k}\). This Z-test can be employed to test the following hypotheses.

\(H_{0}^{SB}\)

There is no short-term (MSR) break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0k}}\) originates from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{1}\) under \({ }H_{0}\)).

\(H_{1}^{SB}\)

There is a short-term (MSR) break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0k}}\) does not originate from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{1}\) under \({ }H_{{\text{a}}}\)).

\(H_{0}^{LB}\)

There is no long-term break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}k}}\) originates from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{2}\) under \({ }H_{0}\)).

\(H_{1}^{LB}\)

There is a long-term break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}k}}\) does not originate from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{2}\) under \({ }H_{{\text{a}}}\)).

\(H_{0}^{CRB}\)

There is no correlatedness break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2k}}\) originates from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{3}\) under \({ }H_{0}\)).

\(H_{1}^{CRB}\)

There is a correlatedness break between X and Y in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile

(or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2k}}\) does not originate from the same normal distribution as the others in \(P_{3}\) under \({ }H_{{\text{a}}}\)).

The basic structure of testing the hypotheses of our main concern in Fig. 1 shows that a long-term break (\(H_{1}^{LB}\)) or a correlatedness break (\(H_{1}^{CRB}\)) is caused by a short-term break (\(H_{1}^{SB}\)).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Basic causal structure of testing contagion

As a break in the established relationship is expected to occur at low quantiles corresponding to crisis periods, the contagion test can use the slope estimates at low quantiles, namely, \({ }\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}01}} , \hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}1}} ,\) or \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}21}}\). The selection of the low quantile may be justified by the fact that during a crisis period, when \(\Delta X_{t}\) decreases, \(\Delta Y_{t }\) tends to decrease more significantly than usual. Hence, a significant change is expected to occur in \(\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}\) at low quantile (recall \(\Delta Y_{t} /\Delta X_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) under the MIH based on Eq. 7) or a structural break in (left) tail dependence, which is an actual dimension of the contagion effects (Bussetti and Harvey 2011; Rodriguez 2007). In summary, quantile regression is employed to handle contagion as a left-tail event. By rejecting \(H_{0}^{SB}\), \(H_{0}^{LB}\), and \(H_{0}^{CRB}\) using \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}01}} , \hat{\gamma }_{{{\text{L}}1}} ,\) and \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}21}}\), respectively, breaks can be identified in the short-term relationship, long-term relationship, and correlatedness during crisis periods, respectively.

Contagion dynamics against the MIH

Based on the null MIH and Eq. 6, various kinds of situations can occur when a shock hits market X. Changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{x} , \eta_{y} } \right)\) and volatility spillover based on Eq. 8 caused by a shock create structure breaks in short- or long-term effect or correlatedness (\(\beta_{L0}\),\({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\), \(\beta_{L2}\)). There are eight possible cases of breaks in short- or long-term effect or correlatedness (\(\beta_{L0}\), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\), \(\beta_{L2} )\) resulting from the changes in \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{x} , \eta_{y} } \right)\). Table 1 summarizes the eight possible situations (S1–S8) with causality relations between \(\left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \eta_{x} , \eta_{y} } \right)\) and (\(\beta_{L0}\), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}}\), \(\beta_{L2} )\) when a shock hits market X. Appendix 7 verifies the causality relationships between the eight situations in Table 1. The last column of Table 1 addresses the contagion check. “No” and “Contained”Footnote 8 indicate avoidance of contagion. “Additional check required” indicates that a further check is needed to determine contagion.

Table 1 Contagion dynamics table

Remark 7

Handling the contagion test via classification. As noted in Table 1, there is a one-to-one relationship between causal volatility and structural breaks for S-1 to S-4 (i.e., it contains no UND), while there is no such one-to-one relationship for S-5 to S-8 (i.e., it contains UNDs).Footnote 9 S-1 covers a normal MIH or a “fully integrated market.” S-2 and S-3 handle the contagion bias from correlatedness break (CRB) or long-term break (LB), which were addressed by Forbes and Rigobon (2002). S-4 handles bias from a short-term break (SB), which is related to Favero and Giavazzi (2002), who employed a nonlinearity technique to detect a short-term effect in its opposite direction to observe “flight to quality” (p.241). S-5 contains contagion by exclusively keeping \(\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }} \left( {MSR} \right);\) hence, it might be considered to handle contagion bias from a long-term break (LB) and correlatedness break (CRB) simultaneously. S-5 is unlikely to occur in reality, as LB and CRB occur simultaneously with no short-term break (NSB). S-6, S-7, and S-8 are concerned with the possible bias from the SB, as noted in S-4. In these cases, further checks are necessary to identify contagion, as SB, CRB, SB, and LB occur simultaneously.

Remark 8

S2–S5 in an economic or financial context. According to Forbes and Rigobon (2002), CRB may be explained by aggregate or global shocks that simultaneously affect the fundamentals of several economies. For instance, a rise in the international interest rate, a contraction in the supply of international capital, or a decline in demand for international capital could simultaneously slow down economic growth in a number of countries. LB may be explained by how a shock to one country could affect the fundamentals in other countries. This case could work through a number of real linkages, such as trade or policy coordination. Trade could link economies, as a devaluation in one country would increase the competitiveness of that country’s goods, potentially decreasing the competitiveness of other countries. This could have a direct effect on a country’s sales and output and, if the loss in competitiveness is severe enough, increase expectations of exchange rate devaluation and/or lead to an attack on the country’s currency. In these cases, well-defined types of LB or CRB are handled, making it less difficult to handle contagion.

Remark 9

S6–S8 in an economic or financial context. These cases refer to any increased market comovement that cannot be explained by the S2–S5 cases. Masson (1998) presented a theory of multiple equilibria, which shows that a crisis in one country can be used as a sunspot for another. The shift from a good to a bad equilibrium is driven by a change in investor expectations rather than real linkages. Theories explaining contagion are based on multiple equilibria, capital market liquidity, investor psychology, and political economy. Valdés (2000) developed a model based on capital market liquidity and argued that a crisis in one country can cause a liquidity shock to market participants. This could force portfolio recomposition and drive a sell-off of certain asset classes, which would lower asset prices in countries not affected by the initial crisis. Mullainathan (2002) focused on investor psychology and argued that investors recall past events imperfectly. A crisis in one country could trigger memories of past crises, which would cause investors to recompute their priors regarding variables such as debt default and assign a higher probability to a bad state. The resulting downward comovement in prices would occur because memories rather than fundamentals are correlated. Drazen (2000) proposed that political economy can drive price comovements, such as during the European devaluations of 1993. For instance, if political pressure drives central bank presidents to maintain an existing exchange rate regime, when one country abandons its regime, the political costs of other countries would be reduced, changing their regime. This effect could generate bunching in the timing of the economic policy shifts. In these cases, relatively more complicated types of LB or CRB are handled; hence, it would be rather difficult to handle contagion.

Identifying contagion using a Bayesian approach

The change in the short-term effect \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or the MSR) is further checked to determine whether it is the main force behind a break in the long-term effect or correlatedness (LB or CRB). The Bayesian approach was used to calculate the related posterior probabilities. Following the definition of contagion, its occurrence can be investigated by calculating the posterior probabilities of P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) or P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right).\) The posterior probability of P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right)\) (\({\text{P}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right)\)) is interpreted as the probability that LB (CRB) is caused by SB when LB (CRB) is given or as the ratio of SB to LB (CRB). For S-1, S-2, S-3, and S-5, P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = 0\), as they belong to NSB. For S-4, P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = 0,\) as it belongs to the NLB and NCRB simultaneously. Thus, either no or contained contagion was reported for S-1 to S-5.

For S-6, \({\text{P}}\left( {\text{SB|CRB}} \right) > 0\) must be calculated, which belongs to SB and CRB. As the correlatedness \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) consists of independent multiplication components of \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)\), an additional check is necessary to decide whether CRB is mainly due to the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) or in \(\left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)\). The posterior probability CRB caused by changes in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or SB) is calculated as \({\text{P}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = \frac{{P\left( {SB} \right)P\left( {CRB{|}SB} \right)}}{{P\left( {CRB} \right)}}\). For S-7, \({\text{P}}\left( {\text{SB|LB}} \right) > 0\) must be calculated, which belongs to SB and LB. As the long-term effect \(\gamma_{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) consists of independent multiplication components of \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\frac{{\left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\), an additional check is required to determine whether LB is mainly due to the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) or in \(\frac{{\left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\). The posterior probability that LB is caused by changes in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or SB) is calculated as \({\text{P}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = \frac{{P\left( {SB} \right)P\left( {LB{|}SB} \right)}}{{P\left( {LB} \right)}}\). For S-8, it must be further verified that LB or CRB is due to the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or SB) by calculating the posterior probabilities of P \(\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) {\text{and}} P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right)\).

The present contagion test procedure is summarized as follows:

  1. (i)

    Assume Eq. 3 for target market Y and source market X,

    $$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt} \\ & = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma_{L} X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{1t} = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{L2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{Lt} \\ \end{aligned}$$
  2. (ii)

    Establish null hypotheses for coefficients in the \(\frac{k}{N + 1}{\text{th}}\) quantile that correspond to the crisis period across fixed N quantiles: \(H_{0}^{SB} \;{\text{versus}}\; H_{1}^{SB}\)(short-term break), \(H_{0}^{LB} \;{\text{versus}}\;H_{1}^{LB}\)(long-term break), and \(H_{0}^{CRB} \;{\text{versus}}\; H_{1}^{CRB}\) (correlatedness break).

  3. (iii)

    Apply the Z-test given by Eq. 9 with selected \(k\) for \({ }(\beta_{{{\text{L}}0}} ,\gamma_{{\text{L}}} ,\beta_{{{\text{L}}2}} )\).

  4. (iv)

    Using the test results from step (iii) and Table 1, complete the Bayesian test by calculating the posterior probabilities of P(SBLB) and P(SBCRB). If the posterior probability is greater than a specified value \(\theta_{0}\), contagion is declared.

To calculate the posterior probabilities of \(P\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) and P\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right),{ }\) the p values from step (iii) of the contagion test process were used to estimate the related probabilities. Recalling that the p value is the probability under \({\text{H}}_{0}\), to obtain a result equal to or greater than what was observed, p values from testing \(H_{0}^{SB} , H_{0}^{LB}\) and \(H_{0}^{CRB}\) were used as estimates of \(P\left( {SB} \right), P\left( {{\text{L}}B} \right), {\text{and}} P\left( {{\text{CR}}B} \right)\), respectively. In addition, \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{L}}B{|}SB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{CR}}B{|}SB} \right)\) could be estimated from the given testing results (Appendix 8, Eqs. 12 and 13).

Empirical results and discussion

Dynamic analysis of the GFC among developed markets

This study examined the dynamic transmission of the GFC to 22 developed equity markets between 2007 and 2009 using the analytical Bayesian approach developed above.

Data

Data from the Thompson Reuters DataStream were used, which provided equity market indices for most countries. Using the U.S. financial market as the origin of the GFC, 22 developed markets were examined (see Appendix 9 for equity market indices by country and DataStream code). These countries were selected based on the developed market lists provided by Dow Jones, the FTSE Group, MSCI, Russell, and S&P. These data providers classify the market status of countries as “developed” or “emerging” based on their economic size, wealth, and the quality, depth, and breadth of their markets. This study selected countries included in all the developed market lists provided by these data providers.Footnote 10 The data consisted of the daily prices of the aggregate stock indices. This study used a 2-day moving average return to overcome the issue posed by geographical time differences in the analysis of the U.S. financial contagion to other countries (Forbes and Rigobon 2002). The sample period, spanning approximately 6 years, from January 2004 to October 2009, focused on the GFC (2007–2009). The crisis began in the U.S. subprime mortgage market in 2007 and led to sharp declines in equity markets worldwide, affecting both developed and emerging markets (Aloui et al. 2011; Dungey and Gajurel 2014; Frank and Hesse 2009; Horta et al. 2010; Hwang et al. 2013; Kenourgios et al. 2011; Samarakoon 2011). As the purpose of this study was to examine the spread of the U.S. financial crisis to developed countries during the GFC, this study did not consider data from November 2009 onwards, when Greece revealed that its budget deficit was more than twice the value it previously disclosed, which signaled the beginning of the European sovereign debt crisis. Including data from November 2009 onward may lead to unexpected results owing to the effect of the European sovereign debt crisis. Thus, the sample period was ended in October 2009 to alleviate the possible noise from other financial market crises. Following the crisis related to the bankruptcy of WorldCom in June 2002, no significant financial crisis was reported until the beginning of the subprime crisis in the U.S. Therefore, this sample period, which began in January 2004 and continued through October 2009, covered an extended period of tranquility followed by the GFC. The sample included 1522 daily observations. According to Brière et al. (2012), it is difficult to identify precise dates that correspond to a crisis, and previous studies on financial contagion during the GFC have used slightly different crisis periods. To identify the crisis period, this study selected observation dates included within most crisis periods considered in previous studies on the GFC. This study assumed that the crisis period began on August 1, 2007 and continued until March 31, 2009. Table 2 reports the summary statistics of the aggregate stock market indices’ daily returns for developed markets during the crisis and tranquil periods. Compared with the tranquil period, the crisis period had smaller mean returns (− 0.0015 vs. 0.0010) and greater variation (0.0225 vs. 0.0099).

Table 2 Descriptive statistics of aggregate stock market indices

Country-wise contagion analysis of the GFC spread

To explore the dynamic spread of the GFC from U.S. aggregate equity market returns to developed equity market returns, this study utilized the daily returns reported by the DataStream equity index for each country. Each country’s equity market index returns were treated as the outcome variable and U.S. equity market returns as a predictor in the SEECM in Eq. 4.Footnote 11 To implement the test procedure, it was observed that the crisis period belonged to the 5th quantile (Appendix 10); hence, \(k = 1, N = 19\) in the test procedure.

Next, the SEECM was estimated at 5% increments, from the 5th to 95th quantiles, via quantile regression for 22 developed markets. Given the estimates of the quantile regression parameters across the entire range of quantiles of each country’s equity market returns, this study tested whether the crisis period at the 5th quantile experiences short-term (MSR, \(\beta_{L0} ),\) long-term (\({\upgamma }_{L}\)), or correlatedness (\(\beta_{L2} )\) breaks from the aggregate U.S. equity market owing to excess and significant shocks. Table 3 reports the Z-test statistics with the corresponding p values in parentheses for \(\hat{\beta }_{L0}\), \(\hat{\gamma }_{L}\), and \(\hat{\beta }_{L2}\) for the 22 developed countries. Their standard errors were computed using the Markov chain marginal bootstrap resampling method, which is robust to data that are not iid (He and Hu 2002). This study posited hypotheses \(H_{0}^{SB}\) versus \(H_{1}^{SB}\) to test \(\beta_{L0}\), \(H_{0}^{LB}\) versus \(H_{1}^{LB}\) to test \({\upgamma }_{L}\), and \(H_{0}^{CRB}\) versus \(H_{1}^{CRB}\) to test \(\beta_{L2}\) with \(k = 1\) and \(N = 19\).

Table 3 Results of testing breaks in market structure and aggregate equity contagion

According to the S-classifications in Table 1, Figs. 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 present plots of \(\hat{\beta }_{L0}\), \(\hat{\gamma }_{L}\), and \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2}} { }\) across the entire range of quantiles for the markets. The U.S. equity market returns had positive short- and long-term effects on the selected developed market returns (\(\hat{\beta }_{L0} > 0, \hat{\gamma }_{L} > 0\)) and converge to equilibrium (\(- 1 < \hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}1}} < 0\)). Blue, red, and green lines indicate \(\hat{\beta }_{L0}\) (short-term, MSR), \(\hat{\gamma }_{{\text{L}}}\)(long term), and \(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}2}}\)(correlatedness), respectively. Before discussing the test results by country, it should be mentioned that \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0}\) under MIH holds for a specific value of \(\eta_{0}\) (say, \(\eta_{j0} )\) for the jth pair of a selected country and the U.S. market. Each market had a unique factor common with the U.S. market; hence, the market-specific risk of the U.S. market \(\left( {\eta_{x} } \right)\) showed a different value depending on the selected market, namely, \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{j0}\) under the MIH for the jth pair of a selected country and the U.S. market.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-1 markets (no break)

Fig. 3
figure 3

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-2 markets (CRB)

Fig. 4
figure 4

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-3 markets (LB)

Fig. 5
figure 5

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-4 markets (SB)

Fig. 6
figure 6

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-6 markets (SB and CRB)

Fig. 7
figure 7

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-7 markets (SB and LB)

Fig. 8
figure 8

Estimated parameters by quantile for S-8 countries (all breaks)

S-1 markets Austria, Finland, Singapore, and Switzerland maintained established short-and long-term relationships and correlatedness with the U.S. market. According to the S-1 classification rule in Table 1, no contagion was reported. Figure 2 might serve as an example of markets escaping contagion. Overall, it shows that at the 5th quantile, the long-term effect (red lines), correlatedness (green lines), and short-term effect (blue lines) tended to show a decrease, that is, slowdown in comovement and MSR at the 5th quantile.

S-2 markets The equity market returns for Germany and Sweden can be categorized as S-2. These markets suffered from a correlatedness break without short- or long-term breaks during crisis periods. According to the S-2 classification rule in Table 1, firms escape contagion by effectively containing volatility spillovers. Figure 3shows that at the 5th quantile, the long-term (red lines) and short-term effects (blue lines) tended to decrease (i.e., slowdown in comovement and MSR).

S-3 markets The test results for Canada, Israel, and Norway showed no breaks in the short-term and correlatedness and break in the long-term. According to the S-3 classification rule in Table 1, they escaped contagion by keeping the short-term effect unchanged. As shown in Fig. 4, the long-term effect for these markets at the 5th quantile increases compared with the other periods. Other than Israel, Fig. 4 shows that at the 5th quantile correlatedness (green lines) and short-term effect (blue lines) tended to show decreases (slowdown in comovement and MSR). For Israel, the short-term effects and correlatedness were as low as 0.4–0.5, although they suffer from a small increase.

S-4 markets The equity market in Japan was classified as S-4, as it suffered from a short-term break without long-term and correlatedness breaks. As shown in Fig. 5, the shock appeared to increase the short-term effect. According to the S-4 classification rule in Table 1, Japan escapes contagion by maintaining a longer-term equilibrating mechanism. In Japan, the short-term effect (MSR) was as low as 0.3, although it suffers from a small increase.

For the S-6, S-7, and S-8 cases below, the posterior probabilities were estimated to determine contagion, as described in Appendix 8. To obtain the posterior probability, this study estimated the related probabilities using the p values given in Table 3. For instance, Hong Kong had a posterior probability of

$${\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = \frac{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB} \right){\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB{|}SB} \right)}}{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB} \right)}} = \frac{{0.0297 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0344} = 0.4649,$$

where \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{CR}}B} \right)\) were p values for testing short-term and correlatedness break, respectively, in Table 3, and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB{|}SB} \right) = 7/13\) was estimated from Table 3 (i.e., given the 13 SB markets, seven countries show CRB). Thus, the posterior probability that CRB was caused by SB in Hong Kong was estimated as \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) =\) \({\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0297 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0344},1} \right) = 0.4649\) using Eq. 13 of Appendix 8.

S-6 markets The Hong Kong and Irish markets were classified as S-6. The shock affected the short-term effect and correlatedness, while the long-term effect during the crisis period was maintained. According to the classification rule of S-6 and Eq. 13, the posterior probabilities that CRB was caused by SB for Hong Kong and Ireland were estimated as follows:

$${\text{Hong Kong:}}\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0297 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0344},1} \right) = 0.4649$$
$${\text{Ireland:}}\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min }}\left( {\frac{{0.0011 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0001}, 1} \right) = 1$$

For the Hong Kong market, the posterior probability that CRB was caused by SB was relatively low (less than 0.5), indicating that CRB was mainly caused by a change in the market-specific volatility of X (\(\eta_{x}\)). On the other hand, the Irish market revealed \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}IB} \right)\) = 1; in other words, the CRB was caused by SB. Therefore, according to the S-6 classification rule in Table 1, the Hong Kong market appears to have barely escaped contagion by properly containing the break in the short-term effect, while the Irish market appears to have failed to escape contagion. Notice from Fig. 6that the short-term effect (MSR) and correlatedness (comovement) increased at the 5th quantile; however, Hong Kong had less correlatedness increase than Ireland. Clarke and Hardiman (2012) reported that a number of Irish financial institutions faced imminent collapse during the GFC, and the Irish government instigated a €63 billion bank bailout.

S-7 markets The markets in Australia, Belgium, Italy, the Netherlands, and the UK were categorized as S-7. They suffered from short- and long-term breaks but maintained correlatedness with the U.S. market during the crisis period. Using the S-7 classification rule of Table 1 and Eq. 12 of Appendix 8, the posterior probabilities that LB was caused by SB for these countries were calculated as follows:

Australia: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0059 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0159},1} \right) = 0.2854\).

Belgium: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0116 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0075}, 1} \right) = 1\).

Italy: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0206 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0346},1} \right) = 0.4580\).

Netherlands: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0010 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0014},1} \right) = 0.5495\).

UK: \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0411},1} \right) = 0.0019\).

\({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {LB{|}SB} \right) = 10/13\) was calculated using Table 3. Indeed, ten countries showed LB, given the 13 SB markets. From the posterior probabilities above, the LB of markets in Belgium and the Netherlands were mainly caused by SB; hence, they appear to have suffered from contagion (\({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) > 0.5\)). According to the S-7 classification rule in Table 1, Australia, Italy, and the UK escaped contagion by containing a break in the short-term effect. Notice from Fig. 7that both the long-term (comovement) and short-term effects (MSR) increased at the 5th quantile for Belgium and the Netherlands.

The National Bank of Belgium (2017) reported that the 2008–2009 Belgian financial crisis was caused by two of Belgian’s largest banks, Fortis and Dexia, and was exacerbated by the GFC. Masselink and van den Noord (2009) also stated that the negative effects of the financial crisis became more apparent and economic growth came to a grinding halt in the Netherlands in the second quarter of 2008. Such a large contraction was driven not only by the strong fall in world trade but also by negative developments in domestic demand associated with an adverse wealth shock. Specifically, typical Dutch strengths, such as the country’s funded pension system and strong position in world trade, turned out to be vulnerabilities in the wake of the crisis and negatively impacted consumption and investment. This appears to have noticeably increased the long-term effect at 5th quantile for the Netherlands.

S-8 markets Denmark, France, New Zealand, Portugal, and Spain appear to have suffered from all types of breaks (SB, LB, and CRB) during the crisis period. These results correspond to those for S-8. As seen in Fig. 8, the shock directly increased the short- and long-term effects and correlatedness between markets during the crisis period; hence, the posterior probabilities were calculated for these markets using the classification rule of S-8. \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right)\) for these countries were calculated using Eqs. 12 and 13 presented in Appendix 8, as follows:

Denmark:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 0.7692,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0333},1} \right) = 0.0016$$

France:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0002 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0119}, 1} \right) = 0.0129,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0002 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0489},1} \right) = 0.0022$$

New Zealand:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0058 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0114},1} \right) = 0.3914,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0058 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 1$$

Portugal:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0012},1} \right) = 0.0641,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0001 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 0.5385$$

Spain:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0012 \times \frac{10}{{13}}}}{0.0001},1} \right) = 1,\;{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = {\text{min}}\left( {\frac{{0.0012 \times \frac{7}{13}}}{0.0008},1} \right) = 0.8077$$

Based on the posterior probabilities above, the LB or CRB of markets in Denmark, New Zealand, Portugal, and Spain were mainly caused by SB; hence, they appear to have suffer from contagion (\({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) > 0.5\) or \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) > 0.5\)). By contrast, France was found to have escaped contagion by properly containing a break in the long-term effect. Notice a sudden long-term effect decrease for France and increases in all three parameters for the other countries at the 5th quantile (see Fig. 8). Note that the short-term effect was MSR and the long-term effect or correlatedness was comovement.

GFC contagion was reported in Denmark, New Zealand, Portugal, and Spain. The financial crisis in Denmark started in the summer of 2008 with the collapse of the Roskilde Bank, and Denmark experienced a systemic financial crisis in the banking sector until 2010 (Kickert 2013). Several studies have reported significant effects of the GFC on the New Zealand economy (Murphy 2011; Spencer 2012). It has also been reported that the international recession hit Portugal in 2008, and eventually, the country was unable to repay or refine its government debt without the assistance of third parties (Pereira and Wemans 2012). The Great Spanish Depression began in 2008, and Spain was unable to bail out its financial sector; therefore, it had to apply for a €100 billion rescue package under the European Stability Mechanism. Of all European countries, Spain was affected the worst by the GFC (Worldview Report 2009). Although the French financial system also suffered contagion effects from the GFC, it recovered resiliently owing to regulations limiting banks’ debt exposure (Xiao 2009).

These empirical results can be compared with those of Bekeart et al. (2014), in which GFC transmission to 415 country-industry equity portfolios was examined using a factor model. The empirical results of equity market contagion for some countries in Bekeart et al. (2014) reported similar findings as the present results. In sum, the empirical contagion studies of developed markets during crisis presented here indicated that long-term effect, correlatedness, and short-term effect should be decreased to properly contain contagion. During a financial crisis, comovement and MSR determine the behavior of stock returns and residual series. MSR is closely related to liquidity and the possibility of downside risks.

Other contagion cases in the literatures

The literature contains contagion case studies outside those in developed countries. By employing the volatility impulse response function (VIRF) approach, Jin and An (2016) addressed the extent to which the effects of contagion occurred between the BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, China) and the U.S. stock markets and demonstrated how the BRIC stock markets were influenced in the context of the 2007–2009 GFC. Their discussion on the extent and influence of contagion could be made more precise by finding the corresponding S-classification category, as presented in Table 3. Dimitriou et al. (2013) examined the U.S. and BRIC markets and found that decoupling was indicated in the early stages of the crisis; however, linkages reemerged after the collapse of Lehman Brothers. Their findings suggested that BRIC might belong to S-4 of Table 1 (SB, NLB, NCRB) and escape contagion. Luchtenberg and Vu (2015) demonstrated that economic fundamentals, such as trade structure, interest rates, inflation rates, industrial production, regional effects, and investors’ risk aversion, contributed to international contagion, including emerging markets. Such economic fundamentals were included in the common factor \(W_{t}\) or the market-specific factor \(u_{x, t}\) in the present LFM.

Chiang et al. (2007) used the dynamic conditional correlation (DCC) model developed by Engle (2002) to examine the Asian crisis and found that in the early stage of contagion, there was a negative correlation, which was followed by herding behavior that dominated the latter stages of the crisis. A negative correlation at the early stage of contagion indicated NSB, and herding behavior in the later stages of the crisis indicated possible LB or CRB.

Investigating the entire group of emerging markets via the present approach is beyond the scope of this study, as it requires a technically more cautious approach than the developed markets of this study, necessitating regressions at different quantiles from the 5th quantile for each country.

Summary and policy implications

Figure 9 summarizes the test results presented in Table 3. It shows four S-1, five S-7, and five S-8 markets but no S-5 market. The low frequency of S-5 is consistent with Remark 7: long-term and correlatedness breaks hardly occur without a short-term break.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Classifications of the test results from Table 3. This figure shows the number of developed markets in the S class. The figures in parenthesis denote the number of markets that have suffered contagion

More detailed probabilistic contagion assessments are possible by counting the relative frequencies of contagion in each scenario presented in Fig. 9. The contagion odds for markets that experienced SB, LB, or CRB were calculated by estimating the cardinality in relation to each case. For instance, the contagion odds for markets that experienced SB (or SB exclusively) equaled the number of markets with contagion in SB (or SB exclusively) divided by the total number of markets in SB (or SB exclusively). Table 4 reports the contagion odds for the developed markets in various scenarios.

Table 4 The contagion odds

The contagion odds in each cell served as the conditional probability of contagion given market experience. Examining the odds for markets that experience SB, LB, CRB, and their combinations exclusively, indicated within parentheses, revealed that (1) a developed market escaped contagion unless it suffered from SB and LB, SB and CRB, and SB, LB, and CRB exclusively, and (2) a single exclusive break did not cause any contagion regardless of SB, LB, or CRB. These empirical results, presented in Table 4, provided useful implications for policies against market contagion.

When a source market is hit by a significant shock, policymakers of a target market should carefully monitor the short-term effect (\(\hat{\beta }_{{{\text{L}}0}}\), MSR) between their market and source market. Monitoring could be done by checking changes in the target market’s relative speed to the source market in the model. When the short-term effect appears to break (probably increase), it must be recognized as a warning sign that contagion is highly possible. Decision-makers should observe the long-term effect (\(\hat{\gamma }_{L}\)) and correlatedness (\(\hat{\beta }_{L2}\)), classify them into one of the S-types, and establish an economic policy that checks the short-term effect (MSR). As a short-term effect \(\left( {\frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} }}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} }}, MSR} \right)\) is determined by the common factor \({\text{W}}_{{\text{t}}}\) in Eq. 11, the target market can escape contagion by implementing a proper economic plan that influences MSR directly via \({\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}}\), such as adjusting liquidity or providing more information. Target market Y in S-4, S-6, and S-7 appears to contain breaks in short-term effect properly via \({\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}}\) when it escapes contagion with no break in the long-term effect or correlatedness. Finally, S-8 for some target market Y may occasionally be interpreted as a successful recovery from contagion, in which market Y successfully establishes a new sound relationship with market X by restructuring all ties to market X (or via SB, LB, and CRB; see the test results for France S-8).

Conclusions

The literature indicates that contagion tests suffer from various biases, such as the “interdependence, not contagion issue” noted by Forbes and Rigobon (2002, p.2251). Numerous studies have been performed to remove confounding effects or contagion biases from comovement in excess. Solutions have been developed using various models. This study structurally resolved these difficulties by linking LFM and SEECM and applying the Bayesian approach, which determines the identification of the breaks in long-term relationship or correlatedness (or comovement). In addition, the present contagion test defined contagion as a long-term or correlatedness break (or comovement break) mainly caused by a short-term break (or MSR change). Furthermore, this test is easy to implement.

Employing the Bayesian approach, this study successfully addressed various episodes of market contagion. The results revealed the key contagion parameters to be monitored in time-varying situations: contagion odds, short-term effects, long-term effects, and correlatedness. Figures 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7 and 8 strongly suggest that the significant increases in these parameters should be handled with caution. The results presented in Fig. 9 and Table 4 help predict contagion odds in time varying situations. In addition, these results should allow policymakers to develop alternative economic safeguards against contagion via MSR, which depends on liquidity or the possibility of downside risk. Future studies should apply this approach to emerging markets, including the BRIC, during the GFC.

Availability of data and materials

The quantitative data in this paper can be obtained from “Thompson Reuters DataStream”.

Notes

  1. A situation in which the effect between the target and source market is distorted by the presence of the relevant fundamentals. This situation is typically resolved by introducing a proper factor model.

  2. Gagnon and Karolyi (2006) surveyed the financial market contagion history.

  3. Note that \(\beta_{L1}\) represents the scaled inverse of market-specific volatility of market Y from \(\beta_{L1} = - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right) = \frac{{ - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {1 + \eta_{y} } \right)}}{{\left( {1 + \eta_{y} } \right)}} = \frac{ - 1}{{\left( {1 + \eta_{y} } \right)}}\left( {1 - \eta_{y}^{2} } \right) = \frac{ - 1}{{\left( {1 + \eta_{y} } \right)}}\frac{1}{{Var\left( {u_{y,t} } \right)}}\).

  4. Volatility of \(\Delta {\text{Y}}_{{\text{t}}}\) is calculated as variance of \(\Delta {\text{Y}}_{{\text{t}}} \left( { \to 0} \right)\) when \({\text{Y}}_{{{\text{t}} - 1}} - \frac{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{y}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{x}}} } \right)}}{{{\uptheta }_{{\text{x}}} \left( {1 - {\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} } \right)}}{\text{X}}_{{{\text{t}} - 1}} \to 0\) and \(\Delta X_{t} \to 0\). Refer to a simple example in Appendix 1.

  5. No endogeneity under the MIH does not mean that the contemporaneous causality direction runs only in one direction, from X to Y. It means that two markets are completely integrated or completely exchangeable via Eq. 5.

  6. Note that a long-term break or a correlatedness break can be caused by changes in (\({\upeta }_{{\text{x}}}\),\(\upeta _{{\text{y}}}\)) rather than by changes in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\). This case is not considered as contagion here because the break in the long-term relationship or correlatedness is caused by market specific factor.

  7. This holds based on Proposition 3 in Appendix 6 and the weak law of large numbers under \(H_{0}\).

  8. Difference between “NO” and “Contained” is whether volatility spillover given by Eq. 8 occurs. Refer to Verifications of Table 1 in Appendix 7.

  9. Although causal volatility parts for S-6 and S-8 are identical, they are technically different in the sense that the UND for S-6 requires additional causal volatility restrictions for \(\eta_{x}\) and \(\eta_{y}\). See verification of Table 1 in Appendix 7.

  10. The emerging markets will be considered in a separate work because they seem to have been less affected by the GFC and hence it requires quantile regression on different quantile for each emerging market.

  11. We test for unit roots in each return series using the augmented Dickey–Fuller test (Dickey and Fuller 1979) and identify their stationarity. A series without unit root problems is regarded as stationary. Our result shows that no return series has a unit root at the 1% significance level, thereby satisfying the stationarity assumption. Thus, we apply the SEECM to the stationary case.

Abbreviations

MSR:

Market speed ratio

GFC:

Global financial crisis

LFM:

Latent factor model

SEECM:

Single equation error correction model

MIH:

Market integration hypothesis

SB:

Short-term break

LB:

Long-term break

CRB:

Correlatedness break

References

  • Aït-Sahalia Y, Cacho-Diaz J, Laeven R (2015) Modelling financial contagion using mutually exciting jump processes. J Financ Econ 117(4):585–606

    Google Scholar 

  • Aloui R, Aissa MSB, Nguyen DK (2011) Global financial crisis, extreme correlatednesss, and contagion effects: the role of economic structure? J Bank Finance 35(1):130–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Bae KH, Karolyi GA, Stulz RM (2003) A new approach to measuring financial contagion. Rev Financ Stud 16:717–763

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Galbraith JW, Dolado J (1990) Dynamic specification and linear transformations of the autoregressive-distributed lag model. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 52:95–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Dolado J, Galbraith J, Hendry DF (1993) Cointegration, error correction, and the econometric analysis of non-stationary data. Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Baur DG (2013) The degree and structure of dependence—a quantile regression approach. J Bank Finance 37:786–798

    Google Scholar 

  • Baur D, Schulze N (2005) Coexceedances in financial markets—a quantile regression analysis of contagion. Emerg Mark Rev 6:21–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck K (2021) Capital mobility and the synchronization of business cycles: evidence from the European Union. Rev Int Econ 29(4):1065–1079

    Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert G, Harvey CR, Ng A (2005) Market integration and contagion. J Bus 78(1):39–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Bekeart M, Ehrmann M, Fratzscher M (2014) The global crisis and equity market contagion. J Finance 69(6):2597–2649

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyson N, Stahel C, Stulz R (2010) Hedge fund contagion and liquidity shocks. J Finance 65:1789–1816

    Google Scholar 

  • Brière M, Chapelle A, Szafarz A (2012) No contagion, only globalization and flight to quality. J Int Money Finance 21:1729–1744

    Google Scholar 

  • Busetti F, Harvey A (2011) When is a copula constant? A test for changing relationships. J Financ Econom 9:106–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrieri F, Errunza V, Hogan K (2007) Characterizing world market integration through time. J Financ Quant Anal 42(7):915–940

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiang TC, Jeon BN, Li H (2007) Dynamic correlation analysis of financial contagion: evidence from Asian markets. J Int Money Finance 26:1206–1228

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke B, Hardiman N (2012) Crisis in the Irish banking system. UCD Geary Institute Discussion Paper Series WP2012/03. Available via gearywp201203.pdf (ucd.ie)

  • Corsetti G, Pericoli M, Sbracia M (2005) ‘Some contagion, some interdependence’: more pitfalls in tests of financial contagion. J Int Money Finance 24(9):1177–1199

    Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Pericoli M, Sbracia M (2001) Correlation analysis of financial contagion: what one should know before running a test. Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper No.822. Available via correlation analysis of financial contagion: what one should know before running a test (yale.edu)

  • Davidson JEH, Hendry DF, Srba F, Yeo S (1978) Econometric modeling of the aggregate time-series relationship between consumers’ expenditure and income in the United Kingdom. Econ J 88:661–692

    Google Scholar 

  • De Boef S, Keele L (2008) Taking time seriously. Am J Pol Sci 52(1):184–200

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickey D, Fuller WA (1979) Distribution of the estimators for autoregressive time series with a unit root. J Am Stat Assoc 74:427–431

    Google Scholar 

  • Dimitriou D, Kenourgios D, Simos T (2013) Global financial crisis and emerging stock market contagion: a multivariate FIAPARCH–DCC approach. Int Rev Financ Anal 30:46–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A (2000) Political contagion in currency crisis. In: Krugman P (ed) Currency crises. University of Chicago Press, pp 47–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Gajurel D (2014) Equity market contagion during the global financial crisis: evidence from the world’s eight largest economies. Econ Syst 38:161–177

    Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Martin VL (2001) Contagion across financial markets: an empirical assessment. In: New York stock exchange conference paper, pp 16–17

  • Dungey M, Martin VL (2007) Unravelling financial market linkages during crises. J Appl Econom 22:89–119

    Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Renault E (2018) Identifying contagion. J Appl Econom 33(3):227–250

    Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Fry RA, González-Hermosillo B, Martin VL (2005a) International contagion effects from the Russian crisis and the LTCM near-collapse. J Financ Stab 2(1):1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Fry RA, González-Hermosillo B, Martin VL (2005b) Empirical modelling of contagion: a review of methodologies. Quant Finance 5:9–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Milunovich G, Thorp S (2010) Unobservable shocks as carriers of contagion. J Bank Finance 34:1008–1021

    Google Scholar 

  • Dungey M, Fry R, González-Hermosillo B, Martin VL (2011) Transmission of financial crises and contagion: a latent factor approach. Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle RE (2002) Dynamic conditional correlation: a simple class of multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. J Bus Econ Stat 20:339–350

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle RF, Granger CWJ (1987) Cointegration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica 55(3):251–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Favero CA, Giavazzi F (2002) Is the international propagation of financial shocks non-linear? Evidence from the ERM. J Int Econ 57:231–246

    Google Scholar 

  • Forbes K, Rigobon R (2002) No contagion, only interdependence: measuring stock market co-movements. J Finance 43:2223–2261

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank N, Hesse H (2009) Financial spillovers to emerging markets during the global financial crisis. IMF working paper 09/104

  • Gagnon L, Karolyi G (2006) Price and volatility transmission across borders. Financ Mark Inst Instrum 15:107–158

    Google Scholar 

  • He X, Hu F (2002) Markov chain marginal bootstrap. J Am Stat Assoc 97:783–795

    Google Scholar 

  • Horta P, Mendes C, Vieira I (2010) Contagion effects of the subprime crisis in the European NYSE Euronext markets. Port Econ J 9(3):115–140

    Google Scholar 

  • Hwang E, Min H, Kim B, Kim H (2013) Determinants of stock market comovements among US and emerging economies during the US financial crisis. Econ Model 35:338–348

    Google Scholar 

  • Jin X, An X (2016) Global financial crisis and emerging stock market contagion: a volatility impulse response function approach. Res Int Bus Finance 36:179–195

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S, Papaioannou E, Peydró JL (2013) Financial regulation, financial globalization, and the synchronization of economic activity. J Finance 68(3):1179–1228

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenourgios D, Samitas A, Paltalidis N (2011) Financial crises and stock market contagion in a multivariate time-varying asymmetric framework. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 21(1):92–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Kickert W (2013) How the Danish government responded to financial crises. Public Money Manag 33(1):55–62

    Google Scholar 

  • Koenker R (2005) Quantile regression. Cambridge University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehkonen H (2015) Stock market integration and global financial crisis. Rev Finance 19:2039–2094

    Google Scholar 

  • Luchtenberg KF, Vu QV (2015) The 2008 financial crisis: stock market contagion and its determinants. Res Int Bus Finance 33:178–203

    Google Scholar 

  • Masselink M, van den Noord P (2009) The global financial crisis and its effects on the Netherlands. ECFIN country focus, vol 6, no 10. http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/pages/publication16339_en.pdf

  • Masson P (1998) Contagion: monsoonal effects, spillovers, and jumps between multiple equilibria. IMF working paper no. 98/142

  • Mullainathan S (2002) A memory-based model of bounded rationality. Q J Econ 117(3):735–774

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy L (2011) The global financial crisis and the Australian and New Zealand housing markets. J Hous Built Environ 26:335–351

    Google Scholar 

  • National Bank of Belgium (2017) Financial stability report 2017. https://www.nbb.be/en/articles/financial-stability-report-2017

  • Pereira PT, Wemans L (2012) Portugal and the global financial crisis—short-sighted politics, deteriorating public finances and the bailout imperative. Working paper, Department of Economics, ISEG - Lisbon School of Economics and Management

  • Phillips PCB, Wu Y, Yu J (2011) Explosive behavior in the 1990s Nasdaq: When did exuberance escalate asset values? Int Econ Rev 52(1):201–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez JC (2007) Measuring financial contagion: a copula approach. J Empir Finance 14:401–423

    Google Scholar 

  • Samarakoon LP (2011) Stock market correlatedness, contagion, and the U.S. financial crisis: the case of emerging and frontier markets. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 21(6):724–742

    Google Scholar 

  • Spencer G (2012) Prudential lessons from the global financial crisis, a speech delivered to Financial Institutions of NZ 2012 Remuneration Forum in Auckland. Available via Grant Spencer: Prudential lessons from the Global Financial Crisis (bis.org)

  • Valdés R (2000) Emerging market contagion: evidence and theory. Massachusetts Institute of Technology. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.69093

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Worldview Report (2009) The financial crisis in Spain. https://worldview.stratfor.com/article/financial-crisis-spain

  • Xiao Y (2009) French banks amid the global financial crisis. IMF working paper 09/20

Download references

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

Funding

HS Lee’s supported by Sejong University. TY Kim's work was supported by a grant from the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-2019R1F1A1060152).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

HSL conducted the formal analysis, validation and wrote original draft. TYK proposed methodology and revised the paper. Both authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hee Soo Lee.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1. Latent factor model (LFM)

Assume that there are two market stationary returns modeled as follows:

$$X_{t} = \theta_{x} W_{t} + \delta_{x} u_{x,t,} \;Y_{t} = \theta_{y} W_{t} + \delta_{y} u_{y,t}$$
(10)

where \(W_{t}\) represents a common factor with loadings \(\theta_{x}\) and \(\theta_{y}\). The common factors \(W_{t}\) is assumed to follow a stochastic process with zero mean and unit variance, i.e.,\({ } W_{t} \sim \left( {0,1} \right).{ }\) It represents fundamental market volatilities, and its loadings \(\theta_{x}\) and \(\theta_{y}\) indicate the systematic risk levels of markets X and Y, respectively. Systematic risk refers to the risk due to integrated market factors and affects the both markets. The terms \(u_{x,t}\) and \(u_{y,t}\) in Eq. 10 are idiosyncratic factors unique to markets X and Y with the loadings \(\delta_{x}\) and \({\updelta }_{{\text{y}}}\), respectively, and are assumed to follow stochastic processes with zero mean and unit variance, i.e.,\(u_{x,t} \sim \left( {0,1} \right), u_{y, t} \sim \left( {0,1} \right)\). To complete the specification of the model, all factors are assumed to be independent and as a consequence:

$${\text{E}}\left( {u_{x,t} u_{y,t} } \right) = 0, {\text{E}}\left( {u_{x,t} W_{t} } \right) = 0, {\text{E}}\left( {u_{y,t} W_{t} } \right) = 0.$$

To highlight the interrelationships between the two market returns in Eq. 10, the variances and covariance are represented as follows:

$${\text{Cov}}\left( {X_{t} ,Y_{t} } \right) = \theta_{x} \theta_{y} { },\quad {\text{Var}}\left( {X_{t} } \right) = \theta_{x}^{2} + \delta_{x}^{2} ,\quad {\text{Var}}\left( {Y_{t} } \right) = \theta_{y}^{2} + \delta_{y}^{2} .$$

Note that the following equilibrium relationship between \(X_{t}\) and \(Y_{t}\) exists by assuming LFM Eq. 10:

$$Y_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} u_{x,t} + \delta_{y} u_{y,t} .$$

Appendix 2. Single equation error correction model (SEECM)

Assuming that \(X_{t}\) and \(Y_{t}\) are two stationary market returns, the SEECM is specified as

$$\Delta Y_{t} = \alpha + \beta_{0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{t} = \alpha + \beta_{0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{t}$$
(11)

where \(\gamma = - { }\frac{{\beta_{2} }}{{\beta_{1} }},{ }\Delta Y_{t} \equiv Y_{t} - Y_{t - 1} ,{ }\Delta X_{t} \equiv X_{t} - X_{t - 1}\), and \(\varepsilon_{t}\) is the independent and identically distributed (iid) error. The part of the equation within the parentheses in Eq. 11 is the error correction mechanism, where \(\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma X_{t - 1} } \right) = 0\) when X and Y are in equilibrium. The coefficient \(\beta_{0 }\) specifies the short-term effect of an increase in X on an increase in Y, while \(\beta_{1}\) describes the speed at which X and Y return to equilibrium from a state of disequilibrium. The coefficient \(\gamma\) specifies the long-term effect of X on Y. Note that when \(- 1 < \beta_{1} < 0\) (\(\beta_{1} > 0\)), the system converges to equilibrium (diverges from equilibrium). Since \(\beta_{1}\) represents the speed of return to equilibrium (and is therefore the scaled inverse of market-specific volatility of market Y, refer to footnote 2 for its details) and \(\beta_{2} = - \gamma \beta_{1}\) is the long-term relationship adjusted by the corresponding volatility, \(\beta_{2}\) measures the correlatedness between markets X and Y. Recall that the correlatedness together with long-term effect is considered as comovement and the correlation analysis alone suffers from bias in testing contagion (Forbes and Rigobon 2002). Forbes and Rigobon (2002) note that cross-market correlations increase during a crisis period without breaks in the long-term relationship between markets. Long-term effect is related to causation, not correlation.

Dynamic specifications by SEECM allow us to estimate and test for both short- and long-term effects that help us better understand contagion dynamics between two markets. When a shock hits a market, we expect an immediate short-term effect of the shock on the other market. If the shock effect continues, it tends to have a long-term effect and may cause deviation from the equilibrium (or breaks in long-term relationship or correlatedness, i.e., breaks in comovement) between two markets. Thus, SEECM Eq. 11 is suited to dynamically model how a shock occurring in one market influences the other market during crisis. Engle and Granger (1987) propose Eq. 11 as a two-step error correction model for two or more cointegrated time series, whereas the SEECM employed herein applies to two stationary time series (see De Boef and Keele (2008) for details). The concepts of error correction, short-term effect, and equilibrium are not unique to cointegrated data. We assume that a long run equilibrium or relationship exists between stationary \(Y_{t}\) and stationary \(X_{t}\) during a tranquil period. Assuming stationary \((X_{t} , Y_{t} ){ }\) is technically sound in the sense that their relationship is invariant over time during a tranquil period. Note that when deviation from the long run equilibrium occurs, its recovery process, which involves dynamism between X and Y, is modeled by SEECM.

For a simple illustration of stationary SEECM, let’s say we regress the first difference of given one market returns (\(\Delta Y_{t}\)) on one lag of the market returns (\(Y_{t - 1} )\), one lag of the other market returns (\(X_{t - 1} )\), and the first difference of the other market returns (\(\Delta X_{t} )\) as noted in Eq. 11. The coefficients are \({\upbeta }_{0} = 0.3\), \({\upbeta }_{1} = - 0.5\), and \({\upbeta }_{2} = 1.0\), which implies the long-term effect of X on Y, \({\upgamma } = 2\). If X market return were to increase five points (\(\Delta X_{t} = 5)\), market Y return will first increase 1.5 points immediately (5×0.3, the coefficient of \({\upbeta }_{0}\)). Although this increase in X market return might disturb the equilibrium, the SEECM implies that market Y return and market X return have an equilibrium relationship through the error correction process, that is, a 10-point increase in Y (5×2, the coefficient of \({\upgamma }\)). However, the increase in market Y return (or re-equilibration) is not immediate, occurring over future time periods at a rate dictated by \({\upbeta }_{1}\). The largest portion of the movement in market Y return will occur in the next time period when a 5-point increase in Y (10×0.5, the coefficient of \({\upbeta }_{1}\)) will occur. In the following time period, (t + 1), market Y return will increase 2.5 points, increasing 1.25 points at t + 2 and 0.63 points in t + 3 and so on until market Y return has increased 10 points. Thus, market X return has two effects on market Y return: one effect that occurs immediately and another effect that is dispersed across future time periods. This error correction process might be in trouble during crisis periods. For instance, an occurrence of \({\upbeta }_{1} > 0\) or \({\upbeta }_{1} < - 1\) during crisis periods might lead to extreme divergence of market returns.

Appendix 3. Proof of Proposition 1

The following may easily be derived from Eq. 10.

$$\Delta Y_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} } \right) - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} u_{x,t} + \delta_{y} u_{y,t}$$

Then, it is easy to verify that

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} u_{x,t} + \delta_{y} u_{y,t} - \eta_{y} Y_{t - 1} + \eta_{x} \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}X_{t - 1} \\ & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} u_{x,t} + \delta_{y} u_{y,t} - \eta_{y} (\theta_{y} W_{t - 1} + \delta_{y} u_{y,t - 1} ) + \eta_{x} \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}(\theta_{x} W_{t - 1} + \delta_{x} u_{x,t - 1} ) \\ & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t} + \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \eta_{y} \theta_{y} W_{t - 1} + \eta_{x} \theta_{y} W_{t - 1} \\ & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t} + (\eta_{x } - \eta_{y } )\theta_{y} W_{t - 1} . \\ \end{aligned}$$

Thus \(\epsilon_{Lt} = \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t} + (\eta_{x } - \eta_{y } )\theta_{y} W_{t - 1} .\) Now it is easy to see that \(Var(\varepsilon_{Lt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2}\) and \(Cov(\varepsilon_{Lt } , \varepsilon_{{L\left( {t + 1} \right)}} ) = 0\). The proof is complete. Q.E.D

Appendix 4. Two extreme cases of the linked model

If two markets are perfectly integrated into one, then \(\delta_{x} = \delta_{y} , a_{u,t} = b_{u,t}\) and parameters \(\theta_{x} = \theta_{y} , \;{\text{and}}\; \eta_{x} = \eta_{y } = \eta_{0}\) for any \(0 \le \eta_{0} < 1\). Then, \(\Delta Y_{t} = \Delta X_{t}\). In contrast, if two markets are completely independent, then \(\theta_{y} = 0\) or \(\theta_{x} = 0.\) When \(\theta_{y} = 0\;(\theta_{x} = 0)\), we have \(\Delta Y_{t} = - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)Y_{t - 1} + \delta_{y} b_{u,t}\) (\(\Delta {\text{X}}_{{\text{t}}} = - \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)X_{t - 1} + \delta_{x} a_{u,t}\)), where \(\Delta Y_{t}\) (\(\Delta {\text{X}}_{{\text{t}}} )\) is not affected by any factor related to \(X_{t} { }(Y_{t}\)). In other words, the markets do not have a common factor. Of course, \(X_{t} = \delta_{x} u_{x,t }\) and \(Y_{t} = \delta_{y} u_{y,t}\) when \(\theta_{x} = \theta_{y} = 0\).

Appendix 5. Simple illustration of model break scenario from MIH during crisis

In Remark 1, we have the following composition of our linked model

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta Y_{t} & = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt} \\ & = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} \left( {Y_{t - 1} - \gamma_{L} X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{1t} = \beta_{L0} \Delta X_{t} + \beta_{L1} Y_{t - 1} + \beta_{L2} X_{t - 1} + \varepsilon_{Lt} . \\ \end{aligned}$$

where \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (short-term effect), \(\beta_{L1} = \eta_{y} - 1, \gamma_{L} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) (long-term effect), and \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (correlatedness). Errors, \(\varepsilon_{Lt} = \delta_{y} b_{u,t} - \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} a_{u,t} + (\eta_{x } - \eta_{y } )\theta_{y} W_{t - 1}\), are iid over t, \(0 < \eta_{y} < 1\), and \(Var(\varepsilon_{Lt } ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{2} .\)

For a simple illustration of model break scenario from MIH during crisis, we assume MIH with \({\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} = \eta_{x} = 0.5\), \(\theta_{x} = 1\), \(\theta_{y} = 0.3\), \(\delta_{y} = 2, \delta_{x} = 1\). Then \({\upbeta }_{{{\text{M}}0}} = 0.3\), \({\upbeta }_{{{\text{M}}1}} = - 0.5\), and \(\beta_{M2} = 0.15\), which implies the long-term effect of X on Y, \({\upgamma }_{{\text{M}}} = 0.3\). Note that \(\varepsilon_{Mt} = 2b_{u,t} - 0.3a_{u,t}\) and \(Var(\varepsilon_{Mt } ) = 4 + \left( {0.3} \right)^{2} = 4.09\).

During a stress period, herding behavior in both markets might happen which increases \(\eta_{x}\), \(\eta_{y}\), \(\delta_{x}\) and \(\delta_{y}\). We assume that \(\eta_{x} = 0.6, \eta_{y} = 0.7 (\eta_{x} \ne \eta_{y}\)), \(\delta_{x} = 1.1\) and \(\delta_{y} = 2.2\). This immediately brings up volatility increase of market Y via

$$\varepsilon_{Lt} = 2.2b_{u,t} - 0.3 \times 1.1a_{u,t} + \left( {0.6 - 0.7} \right) \times 0.3 \times W_{t - 1}$$

and

$$Var(\varepsilon_{Lt } ) = 4.84 + \left( {0.3 \times 1.1} \right)^{2} + \left( {0.1} \right)^{2} \left( {0.3} \right)^{2} = 4.9498.$$

Recall that the increase of \({\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} = 0.7{ }\) from 0.5 might influence the error correction process. Then the above \({\upvarepsilon }_{{{\text{Lt}}}}\) brings up endogeneity issue (see Remark 3) which leads to causality between two financial markets (from X to Y and from Y to X). These together in turn increase MSR \(\left( {e.g., \theta_{y} /\theta_{x} = 1, } \right)\) and hence short-term effect (\(\beta_{L0} = 1\)). In other words, MSR immediately responds to herding behavior during a crisis period. Then the change in short-term effect \(\beta_{L0}\) might bring about break(s) of long term effect \(\left( {\gamma_{L} = 4/3 = 1 \times 4/3 = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}} \right)\) or correlatedness \(\left( {\beta_{L2} = 0.4 = 1 \times 0.4 = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}} \right)\). This illustrates how an increase of short-term effect or MSR due to herding behavior, the historically well-known event during a stress period in financial or economic context, brings increases of long- term effect as well as correlatedness. In this episode, by controlling \({\upeta }_{{\text{y}}} \;{\text{close}}\;{\text{to}}\;0.6\) via economic policies, one may contain the break in MSR.

Appendix 6. Proposition 3

Under \({\text{ H}}_{0}\), with some regular conditions, the quantile slope estimates \({\hat{\mathbf{\beta }}}_{{{\text{MN}}}} = ({\hat{\beta }}_{{{\text{Mj}}}} )_{{{\text{j}} = 1}}^{{\text{N}}} { }\) have an asymptotically multivariate normal distribution \({\text{N}}({{\varvec{\upbeta}}}_{{{\text{MN}}}} { },{\text{ n}}{\mathbf{V}}\)) for \({{\varvec{\upbeta}}}_{{{\text{MN}}}} = ({\upbeta }_{{\text{j}}} )_{{{\text{j}} = 1}}^{{\text{N}}}\) and a given variance covariance matrix \({\mathbf{V}}_{{3{\text{N}} \times 3{\text{N}}}}\) as the number of observations n increases (Refer to (3.7) of Koenker 2005, p.73).

Appendix 7. Verification of Table 1

Below, we assume that Eq. 3 always holds as general case (i.e., Eq. 6 from the null MIH is a special case of Eq. 3, with \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0}\)). Based on Eq. 3, it is straightforward to observe that \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}, \upgamma _{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\), and \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\). Acceptance of \(\beta_{L0} , \gamma_{L}\), or \(\beta_{L2}\) in a selected quantile (or acceptance of \(H_{0}^{SB} , H_{0}^{LB}\), or \(H_{0}^{CRB} {\text{equivalently}}\)) indicates no change in \(\beta_{L0} , \gamma_{L}\), or \(\beta_{L2}\) (or NSB, NLB, or NCRB) in the quantile, respectively, when a shock hits market X. For each situation, we discuss possible volatility spillover.

(S-1) Acceptance of \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (short-term), \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) (long-term) and \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (correlatedness) together implies no change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\eta_{x} = \eta_{y} = \eta_{0}\). In this case, there is no volatility spillover at all by Eq. 8. Thus, S-1 follows. Clearly, S-1 escapes the contagion, and the contagion check is “NO”.

(S-2) Acceptance of \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (short-term) and rejection of \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (correlatedness) implies no change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and change of \(\eta_{x}\)(or \(\eta_{x}^{{\prime}} )\). Acceptance of \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) (long-term) necessarily implies a change of \(\eta_{y}\)(or \(\eta_{y}^{{\prime}} )\) such that \(\eta_{x}^{{\prime}} = \eta_{y}^{{\prime}}\). Thus, S-2 follows. In this case, there is no volatility spillover at all by Eq. 8, that is,

$$Var({\upvarepsilon }_{{\text{Lt }}} ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( { \eta_{x}^{{\prime}} - \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{ 2} = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} = {\text{Var}}\left( {\varepsilon_{Mt} } \right).$$

Clearly, S-2 escapes contagion, and the contagion check is “NO”.

(S-3) Acceptance of \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (short-term) and \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (correlatedness) implies no change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\eta_{x}\). The rejection of \({\upgamma }_{{\text{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) (long-term) necessarily implies a change of \(\eta_{y}\)(say, \(\eta_{y}^{{\prime}} )\). Thus, S-3 follows. In this case, there is volatility spillover

$$Var({\upvarepsilon }_{{\text{Lt }}} ) = \delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + \left( {\eta_{x} - \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)^{2} \theta_{y}^{ 2} > { }\delta_{y}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} = {\text{Var}}\left( {\varepsilon_{Mt} } \right)$$

and

$$\Delta Y_{t} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\Delta X_{t} - \left( {1 - \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)\left( {Y_{t - 1} - \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x}^{{\prime}} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)}}X_{t - 1} } \right) + \varepsilon_{Lt} .$$

Since a break in short-term effect (MSR) does not occur (or NSB), S-3 escapes the contagion even though there is volatility spillover and the contagion check is “Contained”. In this situation, market Y maintains market stability via controlling \(\eta _{{{y}}}^{{\prime }}\) (or its own market-specific volatility) properly.

(S-4) Rejection of \(\beta _{{{{L}}0}} =\frac{{\theta _{y}}}{{\theta _{x}}}\) (short-term) and acceptance of \(\beta _{{{{L}}2}} = \frac{{\theta _{{{y}}} (1 -\eta _{{{x}}} )}}{{\theta _{x}}}\) (correlatedness) necessarily implies changes in \(\frac{{\theta _{y}}}{{\theta _{x}}}\) and \(\eta _{{{x}}}\) (or \(\frac{{{ {\theta _{{{y}}}^{{\prime }} } }}}{{ {\theta _{{{x}}}^{{\prime }} }}}\) and \(\eta _{{{x}}}^{{\prime }}\)). Acceptance of \(\gamma _{{{L}}} = \frac{{\theta _{{{y}}} (1 -\eta _{{{x}}} )}}{{\theta _{{{x}}} (1 -\eta _{{_{{{y}}} }} )}}\) (long-term) and \(\beta _{{{{L}}2}} = \frac{{\theta _{{{y}}} (1 -\eta _{{{x}}} )}}{{\theta _{x}}}\) (correlatedness) implies no change in \(\eta _{{{y}}}\). Thus, S-4 follows. In this case, there might be volatility change by Eq. 8, that is,

$${\text{Var}}(\upvarepsilon _{{{\text{Lt}}}} ) =\delta _{{{y}}}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{{\theta_{y}^{\prime}} }}{{{\theta_{x}^{\prime} }}}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} + (\eta _{{{x}}}^{{\prime }} -\eta _{{{y}}} )^{2}\theta _{{{y}}}^{{^{\prime}2}} \ne\delta _{{{y}}}^{2} + \left( {\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\delta_{x} } \right)^{2} = {\text{Var}}(\varepsilon _{{{{Mt}}}} )$$

and

$$\Delta {Y_t} = \frac{{\theta _y^{\prime}}}{{\theta _x^{\prime}}}\Delta {X_t} - \left( {1 - {\eta _y}} \right)\left( {{Y_{t - 1}} - \frac{{\theta _y^{\prime}\left( {1 - \eta _x^{\prime}} \right)}}{{\theta _x^{\prime}\left( {1 - {\eta _y}} \right)}}{X_{t - 1}}} \right) + {\varepsilon _{Lt}}.$$

Since a break in the long-term effect and correlatedness (comovement) does not occur (or NLB and NCRB), S-4 escapes the contagion even though there could be volatility spillover and the contagion check is “Contained”. In this situation, market Y maintains market stability via keeping \(\eta _{{{y}}}\) unchanged.

(S-5) Acceptance of \(\beta _{{{{L}}0}} = \frac{{\theta _{y}}}{{\theta _{x}}}\) (short-term) and rejection of \(\beta _{{{{L}}2}} = \frac{{\theta _{{{y}}} (1 -\eta _{{{x}}})}}{{\theta _{x}}}\) (correlatedness) necessarily implies no change in \(\frac{{\theta _{y}}}{{\theta _{x}}}\) and a change in \(\eta _{{{x}}}\) (or \(\eta _{{{x}}}^{{\prime }}\)). In this case, rejection of \(\gamma _{{{L}}} = \frac{{\theta _{{{y}}} (1 -\eta _{{{x}}} )}}{{\theta _{{{x}}} (1 -\eta _{{_{{{y}}} }} )}}\) (long-term) do not produce any required situation for \(\eta _{{{y}}}\) (i.e., UND) but \(\eta _{{{y}}}^{{\prime }} \ne\eta _{{{x}}}^{{\prime }}\). Thus, S-5 follows. In this case, volatility spillover clearly occurs by Eq. 8 as follows:

$${\text{Var}}({{{\upvarepsilon }}_{{\text{Lt}}}}) = \delta _y^2 + {\left( {\frac{{{\theta _y}}}{{{\theta _x}}}{\delta _x}} \right)^2} + {\left( {\eta _x^{\prime} -\eta _y^{\prime}} \right)^2}\theta _y^{2} > \delta _y^2 + {\left( {\frac{{{\theta _y}}}{{{\theta _x}}}{\delta _x}} \right)^2} = {\text{Var}}\left( {{\varepsilon _{Mt}}} \right)$$

and

$$\Delta {Y_t} = \frac{{{\theta _y}}}{{{\theta _x}}}\Delta {X_t} - \left( {1 - \eta _y^{\prime}} \right)\left( {{Y_{t - 1}} - \frac{{{\theta _y}\left( {1 - \eta _x^{\prime}} \right)}}{{{\theta _x}\left( {1 - \eta _y^{\prime}} \right)}}{X_{t - 1}}} \right) + {\varepsilon _{Lt}}.$$

Since a break in short-term effect (MSR) does not occur (or NSB), S-5 escapes the contagion even though there is volatility spillover and the contagion check is “Contained”. In this situation, market Y maintains market stability by keeping \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (MSR) unchanged.

(S-6) Rejection of \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (short-term) implies a change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\). In this case, acceptance of \({\gamma }_{{{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) (long-term) and rejection of \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (correlatedness) produce some required condition for \(\eta_{y}\) and \(\eta_{x}\) (e.g., \(\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} \left( {1 - \eta_{x}^{{\prime}} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} \left( {1 - \eta_{y}^{{\prime}} } \right)}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\)) although they are allowed to vary. Thus, (S-6) follows. Since the statuses of \(\eta_{x}\) and \(\eta_{y}\) are unknown (i.e., UND) with breaks in short-term effect and correlatedness (or SB and CRB), this case needs a further check to conclude contagion, and the contagion check is “Additional check required”. Following the definition of the contagion, contagion occurs if the correlatedness break (or break in \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\)) is mainly caused by a change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\)(MSR) not by the change in \(\left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)\).

(S-7) Rejection of \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (short-term) and acceptance of \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (correlatedness) necessarily implies a change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) and \(\eta_{x}\) (or \(\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }}\) and \(\eta_{x}^{{\prime}}\)). In this case, rejection of \({\gamma }_{{{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) (long-term) does not produce any required situation for \(\eta_{y}\). Thus, S-7 follows. Since the status of market-specific volatility of Y (\(\eta_{y}\)) is unknown (i.e., UND) with breaks in short- and long-term effects (or SB and LB), this case needs a further check to conclude contagion, and the contagion check is “Additional check required”. Following the definition of the contagion, contagion occurs if the long-term break (or break in \({\gamma }_{{{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\)) is mainly caused by the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\)(MSR) not by the change either in \(\left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)\) or \(\left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right).\)

(S-8) Rejection of \(\beta_{L0} = \frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (short-term) implies a change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (or \(\frac{{\theta_{y}^{{\prime}} }}{{\theta_{x}^{{\prime}} }}\)). It is trivial to see that rejection of \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\) (correlatedness) and rejection of \({\gamma }_{{{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) (long-term) do not produce any required situation for \(\eta_{y}\) and \(\eta_{x}\). Thus, S-8 follows. Since the statuses of \(\eta_{x}\) and \(\eta_{y}\) are unknown (i.e., UND) with breaks in short- and long-term effects and correlatedness (or SB, LB, and CRB), this case needs a further check to conclude contagion, and the contagion check is “Additional check required”. Following the definition of the contagion, contagion occurs if the long-term break or correlatedness break (or break in \({\gamma }_{{{L}}} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} \left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right)}}\) or break in \(\beta_{L2} = \frac{{\theta_{y} \left( {1 - \eta_{x} } \right)}}{{\theta_{x} }}\)) is mainly caused by the change in \(\frac{{\theta_{y} }}{{\theta_{x} }}\)(MSR) not by the change either in \(\left( { 1 - \eta_{x} } \right)\) or \(\left( {1 - \eta_{y} } \right).\)

Appendix 8. Estimating posterior probabilities \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{S}}B{|}LB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{S}}B{|}CRB} \right)\)

For \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{L}}B{|}SB} \right)\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{CR}}B{|}SB} \right),\) one may estimate them from given testing results, which test \(H_{0}^{SB} , H_{0}^{LB}\) and \(H_{0}^{CRB}\) across \(m\) different target market Ys given the same source market X. Suppose that tests yield the \({\text{m}}_{1} {\text{Y}}\) s having experienced SB, \({\text{m}}_{2}\) Ys having experienced LB, \(m_{3}\) Ys having experienced CRB, \({\text{m}}_{12} {\text{Y}}\) s having experienced SB and LB, and \({\text{m}}_{13}\) Ys having experienced SB and CRB. Then, \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{L}}B{|}SB} \right) = \frac{{m_{12} }}{{{\text{m}}_{1} }}\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {{\text{CR}}B{|}SB} \right) = \frac{{m_{13} }}{{{\text{m}}_{1} }}.\) Using those estimates of conditional probabilities we obtain \({\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = \frac{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB} \right){\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {LB{|}SB} \right)}}{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {LB} \right)}}\) and \({\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = \frac{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB} \right){\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB{|}SB} \right)}}{{{\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {CRB} \right)}}\). If \({\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}LB} \right)\) or \({\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}CRB} \right)\) exceeds one, the posterior probability is set equal to one. Thus, we have posterior probability estimators as follows:

$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}LB} \right) = min\left( {{\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}LB} \right),1} \right)$$
(12)
$${\hat{\text{P}}}\left( {SB{|}CRB} \right) = min\left( {{\hat{\text{P}}}_{0} \left( {SB{|}CRB} \right),1} \right)$$
(13)

Appendix 9. Names of equity market indices by country and Datastream code

Country/Region

Index name

Code

Australia

AUSTRALIA-DS MARKET $—PRICE INDEX

TOTMAU$

Austria

AUSTRIA-DS Market—PRICE INDEX

TOTMKOE

Belgium

BELGIUM-DS Market—PRICE INDEX

TOTMKBG

Canada

S&P/TSX COMPOSITE INDEX—PRICE INDEX

TTOCOMP

Denmark

MSCI DENMARK—PRICE INDEX

MSDNMKL

Finland

OMX HELSINKI (OMXH)—PRICE INDEX

HEXINDX

France

EUROPE-DS Market—PRICE INDEX

TOTMKER

Germany

DAX 30 PERFORMANCE—PRICE INDEX

DAXINDX

Hong Kong

HANG SENG—PRICE INDEX

HNGKNGI

Ireland

IRELAND-DS MARKET $—PRICE INDEX

TOTMIR$

Israel

ISRAEL TA 100—PRICE INDEX

ISTA100

Italy

ITALY-DS MARKET $—PRICE INDEX

TOTMIT$

Japan

TOPIX—PRICE INDEX

TOKYOSE

Netherland

NETHERLAND-DS Market—PRICE INDEX

TOTMKNL

New Zealand

NEW ZEALAND-DS MARKET $—PRICE INDEX

TOTMNZ$

Norway

NORWAY-DS MARKET $—PRICE INDEX

TOTMNW$

Portugal

PORTUGAL PSI ALL-SHARE—PRICE INDEX

POPSIGN

Singapore

SINGAPORE-DS DS-MARKET EX TMT—PRICE INDEX

TOTXTSG

Spain

MADRID SE GENERAL (IGBM)—PRICE INDEX

MADRIDI

Sweden

OMX STOCKHOLM (OMXS)—PRICE INDEX

SWSEALI

Switzerland

SWITZ-DS Market—PRICE INDEX

TOTMKSW

UK

UK-DS MARKET $—PRICE INDEX

TOTMUK$

US

S&P 500 COMPOSITE—PRICE INDEX

S&PCOMP

Appendix 10. 5th or lower percentile daily returns against the sample periods

See Fig. 10.

Fig. 10
figure 10

Distribution of 5th percentile daily returns by country. This figure shows 5th or lower percentile daily returns by country against the sample period from January 2004 to October 2009. The crisis period from August 2007 to March 2009 is contained within the dotted line box

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lee, H.S., Kim, T.Y. A new analytical approach for identifying market contagion. Financ Innov 8, 39 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-022-00339-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-022-00339-4

Keywords