Optimal stopping investment in a logarithmic utility-based portfolio selection problem
- Xun Li1Email authorView ORCID ID profile,
- Xianping Wu2 and
- Wenxin Zhou1
Received: 8 October 2017
Accepted: 2 November 2017
Published: 17 November 2017
Abstract
Background
In this paper, we study the right time for an investor to stop the investment over a given investment horizon so as to obtain as close to the highest possible wealth as possible, according to a Logarithmic utility-maximization objective involving the portfolio in the drift and volatility terms. The problem is formulated as an optimal stopping problem, although it is non-standard in the sense that the maximum wealth involved is not adapted to the information generated over time.
Methods
By delicate stochastic analysis, the problem is converted to a standard optimal stopping one involving adapted processes.
Results
Numerical examples shed light on the efficiency of the theoretical results.
Conclusion
Our investment problem, which includes the portfolio in the drift and volatility terms of the dynamic systems, makes the problem including multi-dimensional financial assets more realistic and meaningful.
Keywords
Background
Optimal stopping problems, a kind of dynamic optimization problems allowing investors to stop investment any time before the maturity in order to maximize their profits or minimize their costs, are of great interest and of importance in various fields such as science, engineering, economics, management, and particularly in financial investment. In reality, choosing a proper time point to stop investment is of importance to hedge risk and to realize maximum return for investors. In practice, it is extremely hard to find the point at which the realized return is maximized, and therefore the investor tries to sell at a price which is as close to the maximum as possible. To help determine this time point, researchers have made significant effort toward the theory of optimal stopping, and Shiryaev et al. (2008) is one of the typical representatives along this line of research. In the field of mathematical finance, furthermore, optimal stopping has been extensively studied for pricing American-style options, which allow option holders to exercise the options before or at the maturity.
The theory of optimal stopping developed in pricing American options can be further applied to determine an optimal stopping point so as to maximize return from financial investment for economic agents. Nevertheless, it is extremely hard to let investors realize the highest return, and therefore, the objective is to minimize the distance between the time point at which the investment is stopped and that at which the maximum return can be realized. For example, Ceci and Bassan (2004) study the mixed optimal stopping and stochastic control problems with semicontinuous final reward for diffusion processes and give some properties of the value function. Dayanik and Karatzas (2003) investigate the optimal stopping problems for one dimensional diffusions and showed how to reduce the discounted optimal stopping problem for an arbitrary diffusion process to an undiscounted one for standard Brownian motion. Choi et al. (2004) study an investor’s decision to switch from active portfolio management to passive management and modelled it to a mixture of a consumption-portfolio selection problem and an optimal stopping problem. Chang et al. (2009) consider the optimal stopping problem for stochastic differential equations with random coefficients. Shiryaev et al. (2008) address the optimal stopping issue in an equity market by considering a log-normal price process.
The mean-variance approach originated by Markowitz (1952, 1959) has been a cornerstone of asset allocation, investment analysis and risk management. In this literature, Merton’s (1969, 1971, 1973) seminal work is considered a benchmark on continuous-time portfolio selection. The single period model is extended by Li and Ng (2000) for multi-period case and developed by Zhou and Li (2000) for continuous-time one, respectively. The work of Li and Zhou (2006) reveals the high opportunity of a Markowitz mean-variance strategy hitting the expected return target before the maturity date. Naturally, investors also hope to decide when to stop the investment over a given investment horizon so as to maximize their profits. This idea has been further developed to determine the optimal selling time for one stock by Shiryaev et al. (2008), who determined a time point at which investors can sell risky assets as close to the maximum return as possible. This again highlights the efficiency of the mean-variance analysis in the field of investment and portfolio selection. Naturally, an investor also hopes to know the time point to stop the investment over a given investment horizon so as to maximize the profit.
In this paper, we devote to choosing an optimal point at which an investor stops the investment among multi assets for gaining maximum benefit. The investor is expected to maximize her personal utilities and to minimize the difference between the realized return at the stopping point and her potentially maximum return. Compared with the work of Shiryaev et al. (2008), we consider the utility function of a quadratic form instead of a relative error criterion. And since multi financial assets are considered, the drift and volatility terms involve the portfolio. These make our analysis more realistic and meaningful.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In “Formulation” section, we formulate the problem to a two-stage problem in which the investor is expected to maximize her personal utilities and to minimize the difference between the realized return/wealth at the stopping point and her potentially maximum return/wealth. We first derive the optimal portfolio of the sub-problem by stochastic controls methodology. Then substituting the optimal portfolio into the dynamic systems, we have the optimal stopping time problem with the wealth process without the control variable in the drift and volatility terms. Using time-change technique, the nonadapted problem is transformed into a standard optimal stopping problem. Numerical examples are presented in “Methods” section to demonstrate the theoretical results. “Results and discussion” section 4 concludes the work. Some technique details are relegated to an Appendix.
Formulation
Throughout this paper \((\Omega,\mathcal {F},P,\{\mathcal {F}_{s}\}_{s\geq 0})\) is a fixed filtered complete probability space on which defined a standard \(\mathcal {F}_{s}\)-adapted m-dimensional Brownian motion {W(s),s≥0} with W(0)=0, and \(\widehat {T}>0\) is given and fixed, representing the terminal time of an investment horizon.
where b:=(b 1,b 2,⋯,b m )′ is the appreciation rate, σ:=(σ ij ) m×m is the volatility, and σ ′ σ is positive definite.
where π i (s), i=1,2⋯,m, denotes the total market value of the agent’s wealth in the i-th stock. We call the process π(s):=(π 1(s),π 2(s),⋯,π m (s))′ a portfolio of the agent.
Note that the above two-stage problem setting is very insightful. It is more realistic than those addressed in Shiryaev et al. (2008) since m-dimensional financial assets are considered and the drift and volatility terms involving the portfolio.
Methods
where 1=(1,1,⋯,1)′ is an m-dimensional column vector.
where θ=σ −1(b−r 1).
where G(t,y)=1−2α G 1(t,y)+α 2 G 2(t,y).
Theoretically, we have derived a region in which the venture capitalist may sell the shares they hold, given the pre-determined relationship between her target return and the expected maximum return.
Theorem 1
Results and discussion
To investigate comparative statics, we present one numerical example in which we change the value of the parameter α. Following the standard approach for estimating the above problem via the finite difference approach, we solve the mathematical formulation given in Eq. (16) by imposing a uniform grid on the (t,y) domain. A Crank-Nicolson scheme is adopted for the discretization of the partial differential equation and the semi-infinite interval for y is truncated at a sufficiently large value of y. The derivative boundary condition is discretized using a forward difference approximation. For the results shown below, we take the grid spacing to be 0.005 for y and 0.001 for t dimensions.
α=0.8,0.85,0.9,0.95,1
Conclusion
This paper considers an optimal stopping time point for the investor who is expected to maximize her personal utilities and to minimize the difference between the realized return at the stopping point and her potentially maximum return. Our utility function of a quadratic form is more general than that of a fraction form where the denominator may be zero in Shiryaev et al. (2008). Furthermore, our investment problem, which includes the portfolio in the drift and volatility terms of the dynamic systems, makes the problem including multi-dimensional financial assets more realistic and meaningful.
Appendix A: expression of function G 1
Appendix B: expression of function G 2
Declarations
Funding
This work is supported by Research Grants Council of Hong Kong under grant no. 519913 and 15224215, and National Natural Science Foundation of China (No.11571124).
Authors’ contributions
All authors read and approved the final manuscript.
Competing interests
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Publisher’s Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
Authors’ Affiliations
References
- Ceci, C, Bassan B (2004) Mixed optimal stopping and stochastic control problems with semicontinuous final reward for diffusion processes. Stochast Stochast Rep 76:323–337.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Chang, MH, Pang T, Yong J (2009) Optimal stopping problem for stochastic differential equations with random coefficients. SIAM J Control Optim 48:941–971.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Choi, K, Koo H, Kwak D (2004) Optimal stopping of active portfolio management. Ann Econ Finance 5:93–126.Google Scholar
- Dayanik, S, Karatzas I (2003) On the optimal stopping problem for one-dimensional diffusions. Stochast Process Appl 107:173–212.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Li, D, Ng WL (2000) Optimal dynamic portfolio selection: Multi-period means-variance formulation. Math Financ 10:387–406.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Li, X, Zhou XY (2006) Continuous-time mean-variance efficiency: The 80% rule. Ann Appl Probab 16:1751–1763.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Markowitz, H (1952) Portfolio selection. J Finance 7:77–91.Google Scholar
- Markowitz, H (1959) Portfolio Selection: Efticient Diversification of Investments.Google Scholar
- Merton, RC (1969) Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time case. Rev Econ Stat 51:247–257.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Merton, RC (1971) Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model. J Econ Theory 3:373–413.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Merton, RC (1973) Theory of rational option pricing. Bell J Econ Manag Sci 4:141–183.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Shiryaev, A, Xu ZQ, Zhou XY (2008) Thou shalt buy and hold. Quant Finan 8:765–776.View ArticleGoogle Scholar
- Zhou, XY, Li D (2000) Continuous-time mean-variance portfolio selection: A stochastic LQ framework. Appl Math Optim 42:19–33.View ArticleGoogle Scholar