Skip to main content

At what levels of financial development does information sharing matter?

Abstract

Background

The purpose of this study is to investigate how an increase in information-sharing bureaus affects financial access.

Methods

We employed contemporary and non-contemporary interactive quantile regressions in 53 African countries for the period 2004–2011. Information-sharing bureaus are proxied with public credit registries and private credit offices. Financial development dynamics involving depth (at overall economic and financial system levels), efficiency (at banking and financial system levels), activity (from banking and financial system perspectives), and size are used.

Results

Two key findings are established. First, the effect of an increase in private credit bureaus is not clearly noticeable on financial access, probably because private credit agencies are still to be established in many countries. Second, an increase in public credit registries for the most part improves financial allocation efficiency and activity (or credit) between the 25th and 75th quartiles.

Conclusions

As a main policy implication, countries in the top and bottom ends of the financial efficiency and activity distributions are unlikely to benefit from enhanced financial allocation efficiency as a result of an increase in public credit registries.

Background

The purpose of this study is to assess how an increase in information-sharing offices affects financial access when existing levels of financial development are taken into account. Recent literature reveals that less than 20% of African households have access to financial services (see IFAD 2011; Asongu et al. 2017). This widespread narrative indicates that a great part of the population on the continent depends on the informal sector for financial services. Some factors limiting access to finance include low population densities in many areas, poor facilities in transport, and limited communication infrastructure. In regions where financial services from the formal sector are available, low-income households and small businesses are for the most part unable to meet certain basic lending requirements, like strict documentation and collateral provision. Even in situations where such conditions are met, cost barriers (like substantial transaction fees) and high minimum deposits of savings could still overwhelmingly restrict financial access.

The above concerns have led to issues of surplus liquidity or excess cash in African formal financial institutions (see Saxegaard 2006; Fouda 2009; Asongu 2014a, p. 70). The authors have suggested measures to curb both the voluntary and involuntary holding of excess liquidity by banks. First, voluntary holding of excess cash can be reduced by: (i) helping banks to track their positions at the central bank to prevent them from keeping reserves above statutory limits; (ii) consolidating institutions that are favorable to interbank lending; and (iii) improving infrastructure to prevent remote bank branches from holding excess reserves essentially due to transportation problems. Second, involuntary keeping of surplus cash can be kept at minimum by: (i) reducing the incapacity of banks to lend in scenarios where interest rates are regulated; (ii) creating conducive conditions for commercial banks to invest surplus liquidity in bond markets; (iii) increasing investment avenues for regional banks via promotion of regional stock exchange markets; and (iv) reducing lending contraction of banks through instruments that encourage competition and mitigate information asymmetry. This line of inquiry is closest to the final point (iii) of the first strand, regarding the improvement of infrastructure.

Over the past decade, information-sharing bureaus have been introduced across the African continent in order to enhance financial access by limiting information asymmetry. Unfortunately, recent empirical literature has been based on the assumption that information-sharing agencies may not be increasing financial access as theoretically anticipated (see Triki and Gajigo 2014). For instance, Asongu et al. (2016) concluded that the effects of information-sharing bureaus have mostly been negative on financial development dynamics in terms of depth, allocation efficiency, and activity. Moreover, as we shall demonstrate in the literature review that follows, there has been very limited scholarly focus on the role of information-sharing agencies on financial access in the African continent.

This study addresses the highlighted gaps by investigating the levels of financial development for which an increase in information-sharing bureaus can most enhance financial access. The interest in considering initial levels of financial development arises because the findings of Asongu et al. (2016) were based on the average values of financial development. It is important to include countries with low, intermediate, and high levels of financial development in the modeling exercise, because blanket policies based on the mean values of financial access may not succeed unless they are contingent on initial levels of financial development and tailored differently across countries with different levels of financial access (see Henderson et al. 2013). In the light of the above insights, the quantile regression empirical strategy is adopted, because existing studies on information sharing have examined the relationship between information-sharing bureaus and financial development using parameter estimates based on the conditional means of financial development variables (Triki and Gajigo 2014; Asongu et al. 2016).

The emphasized research gaps are addressed by answering the following question: can we identify the existing levels of financial development in Africa for which increases in information-sharing bureaus show a strong positive effect on financial access? Addressing this research inquiry is important, because the findings should inform policy makers on ways to lift financial access barriers to enable households and small corporations to maximize their savings and earnings for more productivity, more employment, and higher economic growth. Hence, the contribution of this study is to complement existing literature by investigating how increases in information-sharing offices influence financial access when existing levels of development are considered in the modeling exercise. One of the main results stemming from the econometric analysis is that an increase in public credit registries improves financial efficiency in countries in the middle range of the financial development distribution. This result is intuitive, because for poorly developed financial systems, increasing information-sharing bureaus may in some respects decrease the pace of development, whereas for more developed financial systems, the impact of information sharing may already have been taken into account. It is important to note that some initial conditions (e.g. good infrastructure, saving accounts for the majority of the population and high penetration of information and communication technology) that are essential for information-sharing bureaus to improve financial access may not be apparent in countries with poorly developed financial systems.

The rest of the study is structured as follows. Section 2 discusses the stylized facts, theoretical underpinnings, and empirical literature. The data and methodology are covered in Section 3. The empirical results are presented and discussed in Section 4. Section 5 concludes with future research directions.

Stylized facts, theoretical underpinnings, and empirical literature

Stylized facts

Information-sharing bureaus or credit reference agencies (private credit bureaus and/or public credit registries) are institutions that collect information on the obligations of commercial and individual borrowers from various sources, namely direct investigation and public sources (for businesses), banks and credit card companies (for individuals), and retail lenders (Tchamyou and Asongu 2017). Once the data are collected, the information is consolidated after cross-checking to provide a comprehensive credit report. Such a report is useful for potential creditors. Data from a credit history report can encompass both positive and negative information: (i) positive information (entailing details on all opened and closed credits and repayment behavior) and (ii) negative information (which comprises default data for the most part).

Information-sharing bureaus are essential to enhance financial access in any economy, because they enable the mitigation of the information asymmetry that restricts lenders from offering credit. On the one hand, adverse selection issues are attenuated with information from credit histories. On the other, moral hazard issues are also controlled by limiting default rates and increasing repayment rates. Ultimately, the incremental volume in lending is essential for sectors with limited financial access like micro, small, and medium corporations.

Prior to 2008, information-sharing bureaus were confined to a few countries in the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development and Latin America (see Mylenko 2008). However, the growth of information and communication technology has considerably increased the presence of such information credit offices in sub-Saharan Africa, NorthAfrica, and Central and Eastern Europe. In sub-Saharan Africa, with the exception of South Africa, very few countries possessed well-functioning information-sharing bureaus before 2008. Some nations like Mozambique, Nigeria, and Rwanda have instituted credit offices with the prime objective of boosting banking sector supervision. Greater articulation of controls is made on higher lending rates, and due to lack of appropriate technology and incentives, such credit offices often did not provide timely and accurate information. Before 2008, numerous initiatives were implemented throughout Africa in order to institute private credit bureaus, given demands for data from supervising authorities to consolidate risk management practices on the one hand, and from financial institutions on the other. In response, many countries introduced information-sharing bureaus, including Ghana, Nigeria, Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia.

Theoretical highlights

As documented by Claus and Grimes (2003), two principal strands exist in the theoretical underpinnings of the literature on the linkage between financial intermediaries and information sharing. The first strand investigates liquidity provision by financial institutions, while the second focuses on the capacity of financial intermediaries to modify the risk characteristics of assets. Both strands are founded on the essential economic role of financial intermediation, which is to augment efficiency in allocation by reducing the cost of conveying mobilized deposits from depositors to borrowers. The theories underlying the mission of financial intermediation are based on the literature of imperfect information in the market. Accordingly, the primary task of financial intermediation is to reduce transaction and information costs arising from information asymmetry between lenders and borrowers. Therefore, the establishment of information-sharing bureaus is a channel through which such information can be consolidated. These underpinnings are consistent with the pioneering literature on the relevance of information sharing in financial intermediary efficiency; most notably on models of credit rationing (see Williamson 1986; Stiglitz and Weiss 1981; Jaffee and Russell 1976), ex-post and ex-ante information asymmetry (Diamond and Dybvig 1983), communication on potential borrowers to investors by banks (Leland and Pyle 1977), and diversification with financial intermediaries (Diamond 1984).

The association between information-sharing bureaus and financial access can be seen from the view of adverse selection (from lenders) on the one hand and the perspective of moral hazard (from borrowers) on the other. Information-sharing agencies provide lenders of financial institutions with borrower information and credit histories that enable the reduction of substantial interest rates, which were the previous consequence of adverse selection on the part of financial institutions. When borrowers are granted credit, they automatically become liable to moral hazard, because their economic activities related to granted credit could be concealed in order to reduce compliance with their financial obligations towards the bank or lender. The responsibility therefore falls on the credit bureaus to discipline borrowers on the severe consequences of not complying with their periodic financial obligations. It is within this framework that information-sharing bureaus reduce moral hazard in borrowers, essentially by educating them on the perils of debt defaults and resorting to the informal financial sector as a sustainable alternative to the formal banking sector.

Empirical literature

A considerable bulk of the empirical studies on information sharing has been oriented towards the impact of creditors’ rights to more data on the one hand and the impact of reducing information asymmetry among creditors on the other. The former orientation has for the most part focused on the influence that stronger creditors’ rights have on, inter alia: capital structure (El Ghoul et al. 2012); bankruptcy (Claessens and Klapper 2005; Djankov et al. 2007); and more risk-taking by financial institutions (Houston et al. 2010; Acharya et al. 2011). This last orientation has revolved around investigating how sharing information consolidates credit availability (Djankov et al. 2007; Brown et al. 2009; Triki and Gajigo 2014), mitigates rates of default (Jappelli and Pagano 2002), reduces credit cost (Brown et al. 2009), affects syndicated bank loans (Ivashina 2009; Tanjung et al. 2010), impacts antitrust intervention (Coccorese 2012), and affects corrupt lending (Barth et al. 2009).

The above literature indicates that inquiries have for the most part been dedicated to developed countries, which have comparatively less severe barriers to financial access. However, while a substantial body of studies has been oriented toward the Organisation of Economic Cooperation countries, and on emerging nations in Asia and Latin America, very little scholarly work has been devoted to Africa, a continent with substantially higher constraints to financial access (Asongu et al. 2017).

Macroeconomic evidence on the influence of reducing information asymmetry has been investigated by Galindo and Miller (2001), who concluded that developed countries with credit registries are associated with lower levels of financial restrictions in comparison with their less developed counterparts with credit bureaus. Specifically, public credit registries that are performing well contribute considerably to help reduce the sensitivity of decisions in investment for “cash flow availability,” a characteristic proxy for financial constraint.

A combination of private credit bureaus and public credit offices was employed by Love and Mylenko (2003) with firm-based data from the World Bank Business Environment Survey. They investigated whether financial access constraints are negatively related to credit registries. The findings show that private credit bureaus are linked to higher financial access, whereas public credit registries have no significant impact on decreasing constraints in financial access.

Barth et al. (2009) have investigated the effects of (i) information sharing and (ii) borrower and lender competition on “lending corruption” through information-sharing bureaus using the World Bank Business Environment Survey from 59 nations. The data set consisted of 4000 corporations and private credit agencies in 129 nations. Two main findings are established. First, corrupt lending is reduced by competition in banking and by reducing information asymmetry. Second, competition among firms and the legal environment have had a considerable effect on corrupt lending.

Triki and Gajigo (2014) investigated two principal issues, namely: (i) the impact of information-sharing bureaus on corporations’ access to finance and (ii) the effect of the design of public credit registries on the extent of constraints on financial access. The following key findings are apparent. First, access to finance is comparatively greater in countries with higher numbers of private credit bureaus relative to countries with public credit registries or no information-sharing offices. Second, there is considerable heterogeneity in financial access and on the design of information-sharing bureaus with public credit agencies.

Information-sharing thresholds were investigated by Asongu et al. (2016), who established that information-sharing bureaus have negative effects on financial depth, with the impact from public credit registries comparatively more noticeable. Private credit bureaus have a higher negative impact on banking system efficiency, whereas public credit registries have an insignificant effect. Information-sharing bureaus have negative effects on financial activity, with the impact from public credit registries being comparatively higher. The positive influence of private credit bureaus on financial size is comparatively low.

Methods

Data

As outlined above, this study examines a panel of 53 African countries with data for the period 2004–2011 from World Development Indicators and the Financial Development and Structure Database of the World Bank. The periodicity is constrained by data availability. Consistent with Asongu (2013), four financial development variables are used, namely: depth, efficiency, activity, and size. First, financial depth embodies (i) overall economic depth (M2/GDP)Footnote 1 representing the monetary base plus demand, savings, and time deposits; and (ii) financial system deposits (Fdgdp). Distinguishing between these measures is important, because a substantial bulk of the monetary base in developing nations does not circulate within the formal banking sector. Second, financial allocation efficiency measures the ability of financial intermediaries to transform mobilized deposits into credit for economic agents. Two measurements of efficiency are used, namely: (i) banking system efficiency (using “bank credit on bank deposits: Bcbd”) and (ii) financial system efficiency (using “financial system credit on financial system deposits: Fcfd”). Third, financial activity is measured as the ability of financial institutions to provide credit to economic agents. Two indicators are also used for this dimension of financial development, namely (i) banking system activity (with “private domestic credit by deposit banks: Pcrb”) and (ii) financial system activity (with “private credit by domestic banks and other financial institutions: Pcrbof”). Fourth, financial size is the as the ratio of “deposit bank assets” to “total assets” (“deposit bank assets on central bank assets plus deposit bank assets: Dbacba”). Note that financial ratios that are dependent variables are mostly dimensions identified by the Financial Development and Structure Database of the World Bank.

Consistent with recent information asymmetry literature, information-sharing bureaus are measured by assessing public credit bureaus and private credit registries (Triki and Gajigo 2014; Asongu et al. 2016). Asongu et al. (2016) have documented six distinguishing characteristics between public credit bureaus and private credit registries, notably: purpose, coverage, status, ownership, data sources used, and access. First, whereas private credit registries are made up of public institutions that are constituted within the framework of supervising the banking sector, public credit bureaus are created in response to the need and demand for information on borrowers in the banking market. Hence, data from private credit registries, usually employed to examine the creditworthiness of clients, could also be acknowledged as a collateral benefit or by-product of private credit registries. Second, while the coverage engendered by private credit registries is restricted in terms of information (or data) type and history provided, public credit bureaus extend beyond the scope of large corporations and include small and medium size enterprises (SMEs) that are characterized by richer data and longer histories. Third, whereas public credit bureaus are fundamentally established for profit making, private credit registries are not primarily focused on profits. Fourth, on the issue of ownership, whereas public credit registries belong to governments and/or central banks, the ownership of private credit bureaus revolve outside highlighted establishments (central banks and governments) to include lenders, lenders’ associates, and independent third parties. Fifth, while the data used by private credit registries are sourced from non-bank and bank financial establishments, data from public credit bureaus entails private credit registries, tax authorities, courts and utilities, to sources employed by private credit registries for information. Sixth, access to private credit registries (public credit bureaus) is restricted to providers of information (open to all lender types).

The control variables are also consistent with the recent information asymmetry literature (Asongu et al. 2016), namely, inflation, public investment, GDP growth, trade, and foreign aid. The selected covariates have also been substantially documented in the financial development literature (Osabuohien and Efobi 2013; Huang 2005; Asongu 2014b; Asongu 2015).

First, foreign aid like remittances (Aggarwal et al. 2011; Efobi et al. 2015) could increase financial development if it is not associated with activities that decrease its flow within a country, such as funds captured by developed countries for consultancy services and deposited by corrupt officials from developing countries in tax havens that are under the jurisdictions of developed countries.

Second, there is an abundance of literature that has established a positive growth-finance relationship (see Saint Paul 1992; Greenwood and Jovanovic 1990; Owusu and Odhiambo 2014; Nyasha and Odhiambo 2015a, b). According to these studies, economic growth is linked to decreasing costs in financial intermediation, which is the outcome of higher compensation that entails growing the financial resources devoted to investment. Moreover, the importance of income levels in financial development has been established in both broad (Levine 1997) and Africa-specific (Asongu 2012) studies. Whereas Asongu has shown that countries with high income are linked to greater financial development levels in Africa, Jaffee and Levonian (2001) concluded that higher-income countries are associated with more developed banking system structures. The engaged narrative needs to balance the fact that growth may be linked to financial crises that ultimately reduce financial development (Asongu et al. 2016).

Third, there is a branch of the literature sympathetic to the perspective that policies that are friendly to openness (like trade) are positively linked to financial development (see Huang and Temple 2005; Do and Levchenko 2004).

Fourth, the nexus between investment and financial development has been assessed by Huang (2011), who found a positive connection.

Fifth, some main domestic macroeconomic policies, such as the maintenance of stable and/or low inflation levels, are needed for financial development (Huang, 2011; Boyd et al. 2001; Huybens and Smith 1999). Accordingly, Huybens and Smith (1999) and Boyd et al. (2001) have respectively shown theoretically and empirically that nations with chaotic and/or high inflation are very likely to be associated with smaller, less efficient, and less active financial institutions.

It is important to note that the expected signs of covariates cannot be established without uncertainty, because the corresponding financial development variables conflict in terms of definition and measurement. For example, financial efficiency is measured as the ratio of financial activity (credit) to financial depth (deposits). The definitions and sources of the variables are disclosed in Appendix 1, the summary statistics in Appendix 2, and the correlation matrix in Appendix 3.

Methodology

Consistent with the research question, which is to assess the existing financial development levels for which the influence of information-sharing offices on financial access matters, the study accounts for the existing levels of financial development by employing a quantile regression estimation technique that has been documented to account for initial levels in dependent variables (see Billger and Goel 2009; Okada and Samreth 2012; Asongu and Nwachukwu 2017) with information-sharing bureaus being examined throughout the conditional distributions of the outcome variable (Koenker and Hallock 2001).

Previous literature on information sharing has examined the relationship between information-sharing bureaus and financial development by engaging parameter estimates at the conditional mean of the financial development variables (Triki and Gajigo 2014; Asongu et al. 2016). Whereas mean impacts are relevant, the underlying literature is extended by employing quantile regressions that distinguish existing levels of financial access. Furthermore, while ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions are based on the hypothesis that financial access variables and error terms are normally distributed, such an assumption of error terms that are normally distributed does not hold with quantile regressions.

The quantile regression models parameter estimates at numerous points of the conditional distribution of financial access. Therefore, the technique is in conformity with the motivation of distinguishing between nations with high, intermediate, and low initial levels of financial development.

The θ th quantile estimator of a financial access variable is derived by solving the optimization problem in Eq. (1), which is shown without subscripts for simplicity and ease of presentation.

$$ \underset{\beta \in {R}^k}{ \min}\left[\sum_{i\in \left\{ i:{y}_i\ge {x_i}^{\hbox{'}}\beta \right\}}\theta \left|{y}_i-{x_i}^{\hbox{'}}\beta \right|+\sum_{i\in \left\{ i:{y}_i<{x_i}^{\hbox{'}}\beta \right\}}\left(1-\theta \right)\left|{y}_i-{x_i}^{\hbox{'}}\beta \right|\right] $$
(1)

where θ(0,1). As opposed to OLS, which is fundamentally based on minimizing the sum of squared residuals, with quantile regressions the weighted sum of the absolute deviations is minimized. For instance, the 25th or 75th quartiles (with θ = 0.25 or 0.75 respectively) are estimated by approximately weighting the residuals. The conditional quintile of financial development or y i given x i is:

$$ Qy\left(\theta /{x}_i\right)={x_i}^{\hbox{'}}\beta o $$
(2)

where unique slope parameters are modeled for each θ th specific quintile. This formulation is analogous to E(y/x) = x i′ β in the OLS slope, where parameters are investigated only at the mean of the conditional distribution of financial development. For the model in Eq. (2), the dependent variable y i is a financial development indicator, while x i contains a constant term, foreign aid, trade, GDP growth, public investment, and inflation. As specified in Eq. (2), the linearity in quantiles is appropriate under the assumption of homoscedasticity. This is essentially because if there is heteroscedasticity in the error process, then the quantiles will possess nonlinearities of different degrees.

Results and Discussion

Financial development and public credit registries

Tables 1, 2, 3, and 4 respectively disclose results corresponding to financial depth, financial allocation efficiency, financial activity, and financial size. Irrespective of tables, the left-handside (LHS) presents contemporary estimations, whereas the right-handside (RHS) presents non-contemporary estimations. The motivation for lagging the independent variables on the RHS by one year is to account for endogeneity (see Mlachila et al. 2014; Asongu et al. 2016). The consistent variations in information-sharing estimates between OLS and quantile regressions (with respect to sign, significance, and magnitude of significance) is a justification for the relevance of the problem statement, notably investigating the impact of increasing information-sharing offices on financial development where existing levels of financial development matter.

Table 1 Financial Depth and Public Credit Registries (PCR)
Table 2 Financial Efficiency and Public Credit Registries (PCR)
Table 3 Financial Activity and Public Credit Registries (PCR)
Table 4 Financial Size and Public Credit Registries (PCR)

The findings are explained at three levels, namely, in terms of marginal effect, net effect, and thresholds. The net effect of increasing public credit registries in the 0.10th quintile on the LHS of Table 1 is computed with conditional and unconditional effects of public credit registries. Accordingly, the marginal or conditional effect (from the interaction) is 0.052, while the unconditional impact of public credit registries is −0.945. Hence, the corresponding net effect of increasing public credit registries is −0.832 ([2.155 × 0.052] + −0.945)2. Given that the conditional or marginal impact is positive, the corresponding threshold in public credit registries at which the negative unconditional effect changes from negative to positive is 18.173 (0.945/0.052). The positive threshold is feasible, because it is within the public credit registries’ range (minimum to maximum) as disclosed by the summary statistics (0.00 to 49.80).

It is important to note that whereas the computation of net effects requires statistically significant unconditional and conditional effects, a threshold may be apparent even when only the conditional effect is significant. Consistent with Asongu and De Moor (2017), the notion of threshold is in accordance with Cummins (2000) on the minimum level/threshold in language proficiency before rewards are acquired in a second language. In addition, the definition of threshold is also supported by the critical mass theory, which has been abundantly documented in the literature on economic development (see Roller and Waverman 2001; Ashraf and Galor 2013). A recent application of the threshold or critical mass theory based on interaction variables can be found in Batuo (2015). Therefore, from the perspective of this study, the concept of threshold is not different from: (i) the minimum requirement for the reaping of positive effects (Cummins 2000); (ii) conditions for U-shape and inverted U-shape dynamics (Ashraf and Galor 2013) and (iii) critical mass for positive impacts (Roller and Waverman 2001; Batuo 2015).

Two key results can be established from Table 1 on linkages between financial depth and public credit registries. First, in Panel A on money supply, (i) there are positive thresholds (from contemporary and noncontemporary regressions) in the 10th decile with corresponding negative net effects; and (ii) there is a synergy effect in the 25th quartile on the LHS. It is important to note that threshold values and net effects are disclosed at the bottom of the panels. Second, in Panel B, most significant results are apparent between the 10th decile and 50th quartile with (i) both negative (positive) net effects in the 10th (25th) decile (quartile) and (ii) both positive and synergy effects in the 10th decile and 25th quartile and consistent synergy impacts in the 50th quartile.

The following findings can be established from Table 2 on linkages between financial efficiency and public credit registries. In Panel A (on banking system efficiency) and Panel B (on financial system efficiency), most of the significant estimates are between the 25th and 75th quartiles, with positive net effects and negative thresholds that are not within range.

The main outcome from Table 3 on linkages between financial activity and public credit registries is shown in Panel A (on banking system activity) and Panel B (on financial system activity). It is noteworthy that most of the significant estimates are between the 25th and 75th quartiles, with positive net effects and negative thresholds that are not within range.

In Table 4 on the connections between financial size and public credit registries, most of the significant estimates are between the 25th and 75th quartiles, with positive net effects and negative thresholds that are not within range.

Most of the significant control variables have the expected signs. It is important to note that some of the signs may vary from one table to another, because the financial development variables are by definition inconsistent. The financial development variable of Table 2 (financial efficiency) is the ratio of the financial development variable in Table 3 (financial credit) to the financial development variable in Table 1 (financial deposits).

Financial development and private credit bureaus

Tables 5, 6, 7, and 8 respectively disclose results corresponding to financial depth, financial allocation efficiency, financial activity, and financial size. Irrespective of tables, the left-hand side (LHS) presents contemporary estimations whereas the right-hand side (RHS) presents non-contemporary estimations. Contrary to the findings in Tables 1, 2, 3 and 4 on public credit registries, the marginal, threshold, and net effects of private credit bureaus in Tables 5, 6, 7 and 8 are not clearly apparent. In order to examine why findings corresponding to private credit bureaus are not significant, we assess country-specific averages of information-sharing offices, which we disclosed in Appendix 4. From these country-specific averages, we can reasonably infer that the findings on private credit bureaus are not very significant because of issues in degrees of freedom. Hence, the concluding implications that follow are essentially based on findings connected to public credit registries.

Table 5 Financial Depth and Private Credit Bureaus (PCB)
Table 6 Financial Efficiency and Private Credit Bureaus (PCB)
Table 7 Financial Activity and Private Credit Bureaus (PCB)
Table 8 Financial Size and Private Credit Bureaus (PCB)

Conclusion

The purpose of this study was to investigate how increases in information-sharing bureaus affect financial access. For this purpose, we employ contemporary and noncontemporary interactive quantile regressions in 53 African countries for the period 2004–2011. Information-sharing bureaus are proxied by public credit registries and private credit bureaus. Financial development dynamics associated with depth (at overall economic and financial system levels), efficiency (at banking and financial system levels), activity (from banking and financial system perspectives), and size are used. The following findings were established.

First, the incidence of increasing private credit bureaus is not very apparent on financial access, probably because private credit bureaus are still to be established in many countries. Second, an increase in public credit registries improves financial allocation efficiency and activity (or credit) between the 25th and 75th quartiles for the most part. This result is intuitive, because for poorly developed financial systems, an increase in information-sharing bureaus may in some cases decrease the pace of development, whereas for more developed financial systems, information sharing may already have been taken into account.

As a main policy implication, countries in the top (or highest levels of financial development) and bottom (or lowest levels of financial development) ends of the financial efficiency and activity distributions are unlikely to benefit from enhanced financial allocation efficiency owing to an increase inpublic credit registries. While the absence of positive net effects in the top quantiles may be traced to diseconomies of scale in public credit registries, the absence of positive net impacts in the bottom quantiles could be traceable to the fact that certain levels of financial efficiency and activity are required before the benefits of an increase in public credit registries can be achieved in terms of increasing financial access.

On the relationship between established findings and the literature, two angles are apparent. On the one hand, the findings are broadly consistent with those of Singh et al. (2009), who found that African countries with information-sharing mechanisms for banks are associated with higher levels of financial development. The findings are also aligned with those of Galindo and Miller (2001) in the view that credit registries are more likely to enhance financial development compared with credit bureaus in less-developed countries. On the other hand, our results appear not to be broadly in line with those of Love and Mylenko (2003), who argued that whereas the presence of private registries is associated with a higher share of bank lending and lower constraints on finance, public registries do not have a significant effect on financing constraints. Our results also do not align with those of Triki and Gajigo (2014), who concluded that private credit bureaus are more positively sensitive to finance access, compared with public credit registries. Asongu et al. (2016) found that information-sharing offices negatively affect financial access for the most part, while Asongu et al. (2017) concluded that financial development dynamics respond more positively to private credit bureaus relative to public credit registries.

There are three main shortcomings that merit emphasis. First, we have not reported quantile regression coefficients with which to substantiate the analysis in the study. Accordingly, we adopted a minimalist approach in the interpretation of estimated coefficients. The minimalist approach is based on the understanding that net effects are computed from corresponding significant estimated coefficients and policy inferences are based on net effects. The tables and regressions proliferate very rapidly, and corresponding combinations of “tests of equality of quantile regression coefficients” substantially increase the number of tables we have to produce. Second, measurement error can typically be worse in panel data models. Third, while we have used lagged values of the regressors in order to have some “bite” on endogeneity, there are more formal approaches such as instrumentation with lagged values. This implies that the quantile regressions with contemporaneous regressors are even more likely to be affected by simultaneity bias. We have maintained both contemporary and non-contemporary regressions, because both are still affected by simultaneity bias.

Future studies can improve the extant literature by assessing how the established findings can be improved with information and communication technologies. Moreover, investigating how countries at the top and bottom ends of the financial access distributions can benefit from an increase in public credit registries is also worthwhile. A more robust quantile estimator with which to investigate these suggested lines of inquiry is proposed by Canay (2011). This estimator considers country-specific heterogeneity that is ignored in the current analysis.

Notes

  1. M2 equals Money Supply.

References

  • Acharya V, Amihud Y, Litov L (2011) Creditor rights and corporate risk taking. J Financ Econ 102(1):150–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal R, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Peria MSM (2011) Do remittances promote financial development? J Dev Econ 96(2):255–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf Q, Galor O (2013) The out of Africa hypothesis, human genetic diversity, and comparative economic development. Am Econ Rev 103(1):1–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA (2012) Government quality determinants of stock market performance in African countries. J Afr Bus 13(2):183–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA (2013) Fighting consumer price inflation in Africa: what do dynamics in money, credit, efficiency and size tell us? Journal of Financial Economic Policy 5(1):39–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA (2014a) Correcting inflation with financial dynamic fundamentals: which adjustments matter in Africa? J Afr Bus 15(1):64–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA (2014b) Financial development dynamic thresholds of financial globalisation: evidence from Africa. J Econ Stud 41(2):166–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA (2015) Finance and growth: new evidence from meta-analysis. Manag Financ 41(6):615–639

    Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA, Anyanwu JC, Tchamyou SV (2017) Technology-driven information sharing and conditional financial development in Africa. Inf Technol Dev. doi:10.1080/02681102.2017.1311833

  • Asongu SA, De Moor L (2017) Financial globalisation dynamic thresholds for financial development: evidence from Africa. Eur J Dev Res 29(1):192–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA, Nwachukwu JC (2017) The synergy of financial sector development and information sharing in financial access: propositions and empirical evidence. Res Int Bus Financ 40(April):242–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu SA, Nwachukwu J, Tchamyou SV (2016) Information asymmetry and financial development dynamics in Africa. Review of Development Finance 6(2):126–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barth J, Lin C, Lin P, Song F (2009) Corruption in bank lending to firms: cross-country micro evidence on the beneficial role of competition and information sharing. J Financ Econ 99(3):361–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batuo ME (2015) The role of telecommunications infrastructure in the regional economic growth of Africa. The Journal of Development Areas 49(1):313–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billger SM, Goel RK (2009) Do existing corruption levels matter in controlling corruption? Cross-country quantile regression estimates. J Dev Econ 90(2):299–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd JH, Levine R, Smith BD (2001) The impact of inflation on financial sector performance. J Monet Econ 47(2):221–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown M, Jappelli T, Pagano M (2009) Information sharing and credit: firm-level evidence from transition countries. J Financ Intermed 18(2):151–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canay IA (2011) A simple approach to quantile regression for panel data. Econ J 14(3):368–386

    Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S, Klapper L (2005) Bankruptcy around the world: explanations of its relative use. American Law and Economics Review 7(1):253–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claus I, Grimes A (2003) Asymmetric Information, Financial Intermediation and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism: A Critical Review, NZ Treasury Working Paper No. 13/019. New Zealand Treasury, Wellington

  • Coccorese P (2012) Information sharing, market competition and antitrust intervention: a lesson from the Italian insurance sector. Appl Econ 44(3):351–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummins J (2000) Language, power and pedagogy: bilingual children in the crossfire. Multilingual Matters, Clevedon

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond DW (1984) Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies 51(3):393–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond DW, Dybvig PH (1983) Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. J Polit Econ 91(3):401–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, McLeish C, Shleifer A (2007) Private credit in 129 countries. J Financ Econ 84(2):299–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Do QT, Levchenko AA (2004) Trade and financial development, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3347. International Monetary Fund, Washington

  • Efobi U, Osabuohein SE, Oluwatobi S (2015) One Dollar, One Bank Account: Remittance and Bank Breath in Nigeria. J Int Migr Integration 16(3):761–781.

  • El Ghoul S, Guedhami O, Cho S-S, Suh J (2012) Creditor Rights and Capital Structure: Evidence from International Data, University of Seoul, Korea

    Google Scholar 

  • Fouda OJP (2009) The excess liquidity of banks in franc zone: how to explain the paradox in the CEMAC. Revue Africaine de l’Integration 3(2):1–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Galindo A, Miller M (2001) Can credit registries reduce credit constraints? Empirical evidence on the role of credit registries in firm investment decisions. Inter-American Development Bank Working Paper, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood J, Jovanovic B (1990) Financial development, growth and distribution of income. J Polit Econ 98(5):1076–1107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson DJ, Papageorgiou C, Parmeter CF (2013) Who benefits from financial development? New methods, new evidence. Eur Econ Rev 63(October):47–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houston JF, Lin C, Lin P, Ma Y (2010) Creditor rights, information sharing and bank risk taking. J Financ Econ 96(3):485–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang Y (2011) Private Investment and financial development in a globalised world, Empirical. Economics, 41(1):43-56.

  • Huang Y (2005) What determines financial development? , Bristol University, Discussion Paper No. 05/580, Bristol

  • Huang Y, Temple JRW (2005) Does external trade promote financial development? CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5150, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Huybens E, Smith BD (1999) Inflation, financial markets and long-run real activity. J Monet Econ 43(2):283–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IFAD (2011) “enabling poor rural people to overcome poverty”, conference proceedings, conference on new directions for smallholder agriculture 24–25 January 2011. Rome, IFAD HQ https://www.ifad.org/documents/10180/6b9784c3-73cc-4064-9673-44c4c9c9a9be. Accessed 13 May 2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ivashina V (2009) Asymmetric information effects on loan spreads. J Financ Econ 92(2):300–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee D, Levonian M (2001) Structure of banking systems in developed and transition economies. European Financial Management 7(2):161–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee DM, Russell T (1976) Imperfect information, uncertainty, and credit rationing. Q J Econ 90(4):651–666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jappelli T, Pagano M (2002) Information sharing, lending and default: cross-country evidence. J Bank Financ 26(10):2017–2045

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland HE, Pyle DH (1977) Informational asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation. J Financ 32(2):371–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker R, Hallock FK (2001) Quantile regression. J Econ Perspect 15(4):143–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (1997) Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda. J Econ Lit 35(2):688–726

    Google Scholar 

  • Love I, Mylenko N (2003) Credit reporting and financing constraints, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series No. 3142. The World Bank, Washington

  • Mlachila M, Tapsoba R, Tapsoba SJA (2014) A Quality of Growth Index for Developing Countries: A Proposal, IMF Working Paper No. 14/172, International Monetary Fund, Washington

  • Mylenko N (2008) Developing Credit Reporting in Africa: Opportunities and Challenges, African Finance for the 21st Century, High Level Seminar Organized by the IMF Institute in collaboration with the Joint Africa Institute, Tunis, Tunisia, March 4–5, 2008. http://www.imf.org/external/np/seminars/eng/2008/afrfin/pdf/mylenko.pdf. Accessed 18 May 2016.

  • Nyasha S, Odhiambo NM (2015a) Do banks and stock market spur economic growth? Kenya’s experience. International Journal of Sustainable Economy 7(1):54–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nyasha S, Odhiambo NM (2015b) The impact of banks and stock market development on economic growth in South Africa: an ARDL-bounds testing approach. Contemporary Economics 9(1):93–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Okada K, Samreth S (2012) The effect of foreign aid on corruption: a quantile regression approach. Econ Lett 115(2):240–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osabuohien ES, Efobi ER (2013) Africa’s money in Africa. South African Journal of Economics 81(2):292–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owusu EL, Odhiambo NM (2014) Stock market development and economic growth in Ghana: an ARDL-bounds testing approach. Appl Econ Lett 21(4):229–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roller L-H, Waverman L (2001) Telecommunications infrastructure and economic development: a simultaneous approach. Am Econ Rev 91(4):909–923

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saint Paul G (1992) Technological choice, financial markets and economic development. Eur Econ Rev 36(4):763–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saxegaard M (2006) Excess liquidity and effectiveness of monetary policy: evidence from sub-Saharan Africa, IMF Working Paper No. 06/115. International Monetary Fund, Washington

  • Singh RJ, Kpodar K, Ghura D (2009) Financial deepening in the CFA zone: the role of institutions, IMF Working Paper no. 09/113. Washington

  • Stiglitz JE, Weiss A (1981) Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. Am Econ Rev 71(3):393–410

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanjung YS, Marciano D, Bartle J (2010) Asymmetry Information and Diversification Effect on Loan Pricing in Asia Pacific Region 2006–2010. Faculty of Business & Economics, University of Surabaya, Surabaya

  • Tchamyou VS, Asongu SA (2017) Information sharing and financial sector development in Africa. J Afr Bus 18(1):24–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Triki T, Gajigo O (2014) Credit bureaus and registries and access to finance: new evidence from 42 African countries. Journal of African Development 16(2):73–101

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson SD (1986) Costly monitoring, financial intermediation, and equilibrium credit rationing. J Monet Econ 18(2):159–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

The authors are indebted to the editor and reviewers for their constructive comments.

Funding

The authors are self-funded and have received no funding for this manuscript.

Authors’ contributions

SAA wrote the manuscript while JCN participated in the revision of the manuscript. Both authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Ethics approval and consent to participate

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simplice A. Asongu.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Table 9 Summary statistics (2004–2011)

Appendix 2

Table 10 Correlation Analysis (Uniform sample size: 291)

Appendix 3

Table 11 Definitions of variables

Appendix 4

Table 12 Country-specific average values from information sharing bureaus

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Asongu, S.A., Nwachukwu, J.C. At what levels of financial development does information sharing matter?. Financ Innov 3, 11 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-017-0061-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-017-0061-1

Keywords

JEL classification